wade conclusion LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA
CONCLUSIONS (2): LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA
THE DEBATE about the role of the state in economic development demonstrates
the power of infinite repetition as a weapon of modem scholarship. The issue
is nonnally posed in tenns of the "amount" of state intervention or the "size"
of government. The neoclassical side says that more successful cases show
relatively little intervention in the market, while less successful cases show a
lot (Brazil and Mexico compared to East Asia; or sub-Saharan Africa at the
bottom). It uses this evidence to urge governments to shrink the size of the
state and remove many of its interventions in the market. The political economy side says that the neoclassicals have their facts wrong: the most successful cases show "heavy" or "active" intervention. It concludes from this evidence that governments can, in some circumstances, guide the market to
produce better industrial perfonnance than a free market, even in the absence
of neoclassical-type market failure. But neither side has been noticeably enthusiastic to specify just what evidence would be consistent with its position
and what would not. Both have exercised a selective inattention to data that
would upset their way of looking at things. So the debate about the role of the
state is less a debate than a case of paradigms ("parrot-times") talking past
each other.
I have shown for Taiwan-and suggested for Korea and Japan-that ample
evidence is available in support of both the free market/simulated free market
(FMlsM) and the governed market (GM) theories. This poses an identification
problem. How important are those facts which are consistent with the FMisM
interpretation, and how important are those which are consistent with the GM
approach? My argument is simply that the GM facts are too important to ignore
in an explanation of Taiwan's (and Korea's and Japan's) superior performance. This challenges economics to deploy--or invent-theories which will
make the non-neoclassical facts of East Asia analytically tractable. But does
it also support the prescription that other middle-income countries should try
to govern the market in a broadly similar way (with appropriate adjustment for
national circumstances)?
That depends on the answers to three questions. First, are the conditions of
the international economy as favorable to a rapid, forced, and export-dependent industrialization today as they were for Taiwan and Korea? Second, is
there a general economic rationale for GM policies? Third, can governments
significantly improve their administrative and political capacity to govern the
market?
346 CHAPTER II
CONDITIONS OF THE WORLD EcONOMY
Both the FMlSM and the GM interpretations of East Asian success emphasize
the importance of domestic factors, in particular "right" policies-though
they differ on what constitutes' 'right." Implicitly, they assume that the trajectories of states are parallel and theoretically independent, each separately
subject to the same economic tendencies. Development is a kind of marathon
race, in which each runner's position is a function of his internal resources and
in which all runners could in principle cross the finish line at the same time.
Yet it is clear from what has been said that a good part of the reason for East
Asian success has to do with international factors. These created opportunities
for relatively low-cost industrial production sites to be integrated into the
world economy. In the 1960s several conditions came together to produce at
one and the same time relatively favorable access to industrial country markets, dramatically increased access to international finance, and increasing relocation of production by multinational corporations to low-wage sites. These
conditions created opportunities, but did not detennine which countries would
seize them. Which countries seized them can be explained partly in tenns of
domestic factors-including the existence of an industrial base resulting from
prior import-substitution and the existence of a hard state pursuing GM policies. Location and geopolitical importance are also relevant. The United
States "invited" Taiwan, Korea, and Japan to become economically strong
because of their location on the West's defense perimeter (which made them
more strategic than, say, the Philippines, Indonesia, or Brazil). Japan, the
most dynamic economy of the postwar era, had special ties with Taiwan and
Korea derived from proximity and colonial history. Hence, part of the success
of GM policies in East Asia is due to the favorable historical and international
conditions in which they were implemented (Bienefeld 1982; Brett 1985;
Cumings 1984). To the extent that these factors are different at other times
and places, this throws doubt on the possibilities for other countries at other
times to emulate East Asian success.
A central difference between the world economy of today and that of the
1960s, when Taiwan, Korea, and Japan made big inroads into Western markets, is that it is no longer in an expansionary phase. There has also been a
dramatic fall in the demand for unskilled labor and raw materials per unit of
industrial production. Consequently, developing countries in the 1980s face
an external environment more hostile than in any previous decade since the
Second World War (IMP 1988; Stewart 1988). They are doubly squeezed on
trade and on capital. Growth in world output slowed from 4.1 percent in 1970-
79 to 2.6 percent in 1980-87. Tenns of trade for nonfuel exports from developing countries deteriorated from a 1.1 percent per year decline in 1970-79 to
".a 1.7 percent per year decline in 1980-87. Protection in developed country
markets has increased since the early 1970s, accelerating in the early 19805 to
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 347
the point where by 198621 percent of manufactured goods imported into the
United States and Europe were restricted by quantitative barriers (UNCTAD
1987: table IVA). This protection is being applied with special discrimination
against developing countries. Eighteen percent of manufactured imports from
developed countries were covered by quantitative restrictions, and 31 percent
of manufactured imports from developing countries. Yet manufactured imports from developing countries account for a mere 1.5 percent of manufactured consumption in developed countries. Meanwhile the microelectronics
revolution has reduced the advantage of cheap labor sites, slowing the inflow
of foreign direct investment to developing countries at large. The debt service
burden for indebted developing countries increased sharply in the 1980s,
while voluntary private lending to developing countries almost stopped
(US$3.5 billion in 1987 compared to $73.4 billion in 1980).
On top of these trends has come a sharp increase in the volatility of the
international economy, and therefore much more uncertainty facing developing country governments and producers (UNCTAD 1988a). With the internationalization and deregulation of financial markets, financial capital is ricocheting around the world in amounts thirty to forty times bigger than trade
flows. The relationships between exchange rates and trade, interest rates and
investment, and fiscal and monetary policies have become unhinged (Drucker
1986). Governments' ability to control as fundamental a parameter of economic activity as money supply is diminished, and long-term investment is
depressed. Dealing with currency fluctuations "is like changing the handicap
in golf on every hole," protested the president of Sony recently. "Wouldn't
you lose interest in playing golf eventually? If money scale expands or shrinks
every day in different currencies, how can we make up our minds to invest?"
(Toronto Globe and Mail, 1 June 1987). If Sony finds long-range investment
difficult in current conditions, think of the predicament of would-be exporters
and investors in developing countries with free trade and capital movements.
They are forced to adjust and readjust to signals from the international economy which are essentially short-term. These adj,ustments to price signals that
turn out to be misleading guides to economic fundamentals may cause high
costs. They are "distortionary" in a sense different from but as important as
the conventional meaning in economics, of price misalignments which arise
when an economy has not adjusted sufficiently to international price signals
(Bienefeld 1988).
The implications are ominous for those developing countries that would
seek to "follow the NICS." If many countries are to succeed in increasing their
exports of light manufactures, world trade would have to expand fast; but all
the signs are it will not. The new protectionism is directed especially at the
light manufactured goods which the next tier countries are urged to make their
leading export sectors. Moreover, the East Asian four are "stretching" their
industrial structures as they expand into more advanced sectors, using tech-
348 CHAPTER 11
nology to remain competitive in light manufactures and thereby only slowly
vacating these sectors for others to enter. It will therefore be more difficult for
the others (such as Mexico, Brazil, Thailand, Poland, and Hungary) to use
industrial and trade policies "successfully."
Underlying these ominous trends are shifts in technology which imply potentially far-reaching effects on the competitive position of nations. It is difficult to forecast these effects, for the implications appear to be mixed. The
increase in the capabilities of machines to perfonn the tasks of unskilled labor
may facilitate a shift in the location of production back to the developed countries; but it may also enable some developing countries to become more competitive through better quality control and cheaper engineers. The reduced importance of unprocessed inputs worsens the export prospects of raw material
producers; but the new technologies enable them to process the raw materials
in-country, and free some regions from some of nature's constraints (biotechnologies can make deserts bloom).
Faced with these new dangers and opportunities, what broad lines of economic policy should developing countries follow? We can be fairly sure that
policies to impart an East Asian kind of directional thrust will have a smaller
effect than they did in East Asia, if for no other reason than the less favorable
conditions of the international economy. On the other hand, this does not
mean that FM/sM policies are the better alternative.
We have seen that the confidence with which the neoclassical school prescribes liberalization and privatization cannot be grounded in theory, for the
theory which shows how liberalization and privatization generate growth is
scarcely developed. We have also seen that it cannot be grounded in the experience of the East Asian NICS, for with the partial exception of Hong Kong
they have pursued a mix of policies-many of which are inconsistent with neoclassical prescriptions. Hong Kong, though historically much wealthier than
Taiwan and Korea, has not been doing as well in tenns of income growth and
industrial transfonnation. But what about the other 98 percent of countries?
Does the experience of a broad cross-section of countries provide solid
grounds for the neoclassical confidence? My review of the cross-sectional evidence in chapter 1 suggests not.
Given this, we might usefully deploy a more inductive approach to policy
and policy-making. We can ask what policies the most successful countries
actually adopted, and then construct a rationale for why those policies may
have helped their growth. Due recognition has to be given to the Darwinian or
Malinowskian fallacy in this exercise-the assumption that because something
exists it must be vital to the survival of the organism or society in which it
exists. Translated into East Asian terms, this leads one to argue that because
these most successful countries used high protection, tightly controlled finan-
~"cial systems, and the like, such measures must have been vital to their success.
But what could be called the Ptolemaic fallacy is more prevalent and more
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 349
inhibiting of learning: the assumption that only those features of economic
policy consistent with neoclassical prescriptions could have contributed to superior economic performance, so that everything else can be safely ignored. It
seems useful to err for a change on the side of the former.
A distinction must be made between what is consistent with neoclassical
theory and what is consistent with neoclassical prescription. There is room
within the confines of neoclassical theory for practically any mix of markets
and intervention. Most neoclassical economists argue the costs of government
regulation and industrial targeting and the virtues of very wide choice by individual market agents on (often implicit) empirical grounds. The empirical
significance of market failure has been exaggerated, they say, and government
efforts to repair such failure are likely to make matters worse because government failure is empirically more acute than market failure. 1 In what follows 1
use ideas that are familiar in neoclassical analysis, as well as some that are
unfamiliar, to reach different conclusions about the possible economic benefits
of governed market policies. These conclusions have the merit of being consistent with what the governments of very successful economies-the East
Asian ones-actually did. I state the argument in the form of six prescriptions
for micro- and mesoeconomic interventions. 2
The argument is most relevant to the circumstances of newly industrializing
or newly industrialized countries with per capita incomes in the middle-income range (World Bank 1987a). For the most part I duck the question of its
relevance to the industrialized market economies. I am unclear about how a
world economy would work in which the leading economies, especially the
United States, adopt the kinds of actions endorsed here. Past experience suggests it could be benign: the laissez-faire world of the 1920s had disastrous
economic consequences, while the postwar era of stable but negotiable exchange rates and national controls over capital movements generated steady
expansion. Keynes used his understanding of the prewar boom and bust to
argue passionately in favor of import controls and central bank control of international capital movements as instruments <;>f postwar economic management (Crotty 1983; Polanyi 1957; Bienefeld 1988). But in any case, the lateI On the frontiers of economics the theoretical analysis of market failure has become a minor
growth industry in the 1980s. But note what I call the "Helleiner effect." Gerry Helleiner ob·
serves: "On the frontiers of the discipline. vigorous ex.perimentation can be found in the juggling
of assumptions, the empirical testing of hypotheses. and the adaptation and improvement of both
theoretical and quantitative economic models. Once in the difficult world of policy fonnation,
however. students of economics are prone to forget all of the qualifications and assumptions, and
frequently ajlply instead the simplest and crudest versions of the models they were taught, using,
as they would put it, only 'the basic principles' .• (1981a: 541).
2 Here. as in earlier discussion, I say little about agriculture and agriculture· industry links. But
in many countries the starting point for an internal demand· led strategy must be in farming. See
Adelman 1984; Lipton 1977. I also say little about macropolicies. though such policies affect
competitiveness both directly and indirectly.
350 CHAPTER II
comer industrializers, which constitute only a tiny part of world income
and world markets, can use different principles from those appropriate to the
older industrialized market economies. They can, as have many latecomers
before them, free ride on the (more or less) liberal norms embraced by the
latter out of self-interest. After all, the per capita income of the fifty-two middle-income countries is still, after four decades of self-conscious development, only 10 percent of the per capita income of the "industrialized market
economies" (2 percent for the low-income countries; World Bank 1988: table
I).
My argument is also relevant mainly to noncrisis conditions, when a longerterm view can be taken. Sadly, that currently excludes many countries of subSaharan Africa, the Caribbean, and Latin America. Fully two-thirds of middle-income countries had negative growth of gross domestic investment in
198{}-86, compared with only 2 percent in 1965-80; one-third had negative
growth of GDP (World Bank 1988:table 4). Many have not been investing
enough to maintain essential infrastructure. Many are unable to obtain even
basic economic statistics, because so much activity has moved into grey and
black markets.
I also assume benign political leaders, whose concerns go beyond using
state power to support the affluence of a small group. Some rulers, it is true,
are predatory, in the sense that their efforts to maximize the resource flow
under their control erode the ability of the resource base to deliver future
flows. In these cases enhancing the power and autonomy of the state could be
disastrous. But states vary in terms of the benignness or maliciousness of their
leaders,3 and the more any particular case is toward the benign end of the
spectrum the better the argument applies.
Prescription 1 : Use national policies to promote industrial investment
within the national boundaries, and to channel more of this investment into
industries whose growth is important for the economy's future growth. We
must note at the outset that the objective of such policies is not efficient allocation of resources in a Pareto-optimum sense, but growth and innovation.
This means that the theorems of welfare economics about the conditions of
market failure are largely irrelevant for development purposes. They judge
failure in terms of the allocation of resources to the most efficient uses, rather
than in terms of the generation of new resources (Kaldor 1972). Theories
about market failure in a growth context are not well developed. Here I shall
do no more than sketch out a plausible rationale for national industrial policies.
The first step is to consider why the government should take steps to intenl A vampire state at one extreme, a ruminant state at the other? The vampire extracts so much
as to debilitate; the ruminant grazes the resource base while fertilizing it at the other end. "Ruminant" is John Waterbury's happy term, while "vampire" is the word used by a senior Kenyan
fInance official to describe his own state in the late 19805.
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 351
sify the level of investment and reinvestment within the national boundaries.
The point of interest is not the causal effect of investment on growth, for that
is well established theoretically and empirically (Romer 1987). So also is the
connection between high investment and growth, on the one hand, and high
labor demand; and between high labor demand and high wages. The point of
interest, rather, is the need for political power to focus the investment process
on the national tenitory, which means channeling the options of both domestic
capitalists and foreign capitalists by means of import restrictions, domestic
content requirements, foreign exchange controls, conditions on the admission
of foreign investment, export incentives, technology incentives, and the like.
The reason is that as capital becomes internationally mobile, its owners and
managers have less interest in making long-term investments in any specific
national economy, and hence less interest in the overall development of any
specific economy-including their home base. As wages rise, they may be
inclined to relocate their assets abroad, or divert them into short-term speculative uses at home, or use their influence over state power to keep labor costs
lower than otherwise. From the perspective of a national interest, however,
they should be encouraged or cajoled to reinvest at home, and specifically to
invest in technological improvements as a way of remaining internationally
competitive despite higher wages. For the domestic workforce is not internationally mobile, and its rising real wages are a primary indicator of developmental success. This argument has to be qualified in several ways-by the
desirability of some outward foreign investment in terms of a national interest
test, and by the problems of overcoming purchasing power constraints on the
investment cycle if large export markets are not available. But the qualifications do not change the basic point. Empirically, the work of Alexander Gerschenkron (1962) and Dieter Senghaas (1985), among others, supports the
proposition that the more successful European latecomers used a political
mechanism to channel the competitive process in the direction of higher-wage
and higher-technology activities. (The United States is an exception, where
the same result occurred because of the scarcity pf labor in relation to land and
capital. Hong Kong is also a partial exception. Wages have risen and the benefits of growth have been widely diffused even with capital operating wholly
in terms of an international perspective partly because of its very small size
and partly because of its role as a regional service center. And to repeat, in the
past decade or so it has been less successful in transfonning its industrial base
than Taiwan and Korea.)
The next step is to consider why government efforts to concentrate investment in selected industries may help overall growth and productivity. One
reason involves economies of scale and learning. Whereas neoclassical analysis normally assumes rising cost curves, in many manufacturing processes a
doubling of production volume per unit of time gives rise to a substantial fall
in unit costs, commonly on the order of 20 percent. But the size of plant or
352 CHAPTER II
firm required to achieve these economies of scale is typically large in relation
to the existing assets of firms in developing countries. 4 The risks confronting
potential investors are therefore high, and the investment process will be
slowed if the risks are not partially lifted. If domestic producers are given
assistance to enable them to compete against foreign suppliers in the domestic
market despite higher costs, they may be able to expand their production volume to the point where, thanks to economies of scale and the transactions cost
of imports, they can compete without further assistance.
The Japanese-targeted industry strategy takes this logic further. With the
government providing protection and socializing some of the risks of largescale investment, firms are able to price exports at below current average costs
in order to· gain market share against foreign rivals. The government in effect
carries the firms' negative cash flow through these various forms of subsidy.
As the firms capture market share and increase production, costs eventually
fall to match this "forward" price. Assistance is then removed and applied to
the next set of higher-technology industries to be nurtured to international
competitiveness (Magaziner and Hout 1980).
Gains in productivity come not only from static economies of scale but also
from technological effort based on experience. Even without increases in volume, repetition of production can lead to productivity improvements. Decreases in real unit costs of 100 percent in less than a decade are not unusual
in infant industries that have become internationally competitive (Pack and
Westphal 1986:106). This gain cannot be obtained simply by buying into the
technology; it requires prolonged experience of production, and generally also
investment in a deliberate effort to adapt the technology-so the gain does not
accrue simply by dint of repetition. (There is a difference between, say, steel
and electronics. Learning in a steel plant, where once bought the basic technology will not be changed for a decade, consists of continuous incremental
improvements in operating procedures and equipment. Learning in electronics
consists not only in how to make existing products more efficiently but also in
how to design and produce a new product every nine months-production and
innovation learning, perhaps, or static and dynamic learning.)
In short, the forces that lie behind the orthodox assumption of rising cost
curves are in many manufacturing processes overwhelmed by economies of
scale and learning. Producers who expand production can have falling unit
costs. They can therefore race down these falling cost curves and capture market share from existing producers. However, when the international productivity frontier is itself advancing rapidly (as in electronics), the time needed for
an infant industry to catch up may be long and the amount of assistance large.
This strengthens the case for selective rather than across-the-board assistance.
4 The new flexible manufacturing techniques decrease economies of scale at product level; but
tend to go with increases in scale at firm level, because of rising indirect costs (R&D, marketing).
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 353
Of course, if producers have perfect foresight and if capital and insurance
markets are perfect, these potential cost gains need not warrant state assistance. When markets covering all possible future conditions are available to
all and when lenders base lending decisions on expected future costs and earnings rather than on a firm's existing assets, neoclassical theory could not justify state assistance to finns facing potential economies of scale and learning.
The justification comes from the unreality of these assumptions in developing
country conditions. Borrowing is typically constrained by a finn's existing
assets and lack of reputation. Equity and insurance markets are weak or absent. Building them up is a slow and difficult business. In the meantime government comes in as the "second-best" risk insurer and capital provider, so
as to bring a private cost/benefit calculus more into line with a social cost!
benefit calculus. Max Corden, impeccable neoclassical credentials notwithstanding, concludes that, "in spite of many qualifications, a valid, practically
relevant infant industry argument for subsidization of new manufacturing industries resting on capital market imperfections can be made for many lessdeveloped countries" (1974:255). Governments, in other words, can substitute for missing and difficult-to-develop capital markets (Stiglitz 1989).
A third justification, in addition to scale and learning economies and capital
market imperfections, comes from that most elastic of concepts, "externalities" or "spillovers." In the general sense, external costs or benefits are those
which are created by a firm or other economic agent but which do not bear on
or accrue to it. Simultaneous externalities occur where a finn's potential gains
from an investment are contingent upon complementary decisions by other
finns. Even if all the parties know they would gain by coordinating their investments to capture the externalities, they may face inherent contradictions
of interest, as in a Prisoner's Dilemma game.s Hence market prices may not
adequately signal the interdependence that exists among these investment decisions, and uncoordinated finns may invest at sUboptimal levels from a national perspective. A big push, involving simultaneous expansion of several
industries, can insure the profitability of each investment, even though each
on its own would be unprofitable. One important reason is that such simultaneous expansion helps to overcome the constraint of a small domestic market,
when entry and participation in world trade entails significant costs.
There is also a second kind of externality, sequential rather than simultaneous. Sequential externalities occur where a large upstream plant would, if
built, induce the entry of downstream finns to make use of new profit opportunities created by the upstream finn but not appropriable by it. The upstream
plant brings greater social benefit, in the fonn of induced downstream growth,
than is reflected in its private profit (Biggs and Levy 1988).
S For an introduction to the literature on Prisoner's Dilemma, see Rapoport and Chammah
1965; Lipton 1985; Wade 1988d.
354 CHAPTER II
To the extent that simultaneous and sequential externalities are spatially
concentrated the investment process may become cumulative as more spillovers are generated and more finns enter to secure access to them. Market size
increases, helping to reduce the risk of large-scale investments. In practice,
diseconomies of agglomeration (such as congestion costs) may arise and some
factors will be immobile, so that competitive advantage can shift from established centers to new ones (Brett 1983). We can expect the advantages of
coordinating investment to capture these externalities to be particularly large
where the domestic market is small, where the input-output structure is
"holey," where entrepreneurs with the resources and experience to undertake
large-scale investment are few and far between,6 and where access to world
markets is limited by high transactions costs and trade restrictions. The role of
government is not only to push the process by coordinating upstream industries, but also to lower entry barriers at the downstream end to facilitate the
induced response. Conventional notions of "efficiency" are poor guides to
what the government should do, because when externalities are considered
one may find that a set of microeconomically less efficient industries, considered individually, produce a macroeconomically efficient result through the
linkages between them; while a set of microeconomically efficient industries
may produce a macroeconomically inefficient result. 7
Another justification for governing the market has to do with the adverse
effects of market instabilities on long-tenn investment. Any moderately complex economic system encounters a source of instability arising from the uncertainty inherent in the attempt to match present supply decisions with future
demand decisions. One would expect that if prices and quantities are left
wholly to the instabilities of the market, investment in industries or technologies which require a large commitment of time or capital may not be made,
and a higher than desirable proportion of the economy's investment will go
into quick return projects. Individual finns on their own may be more inclined
to stick within a narrow range of familiar product lines than branch out into
6 In situations characterized by lack of efficient risk-sharing institutions such as stock markets,
• 'the size of the entrepreneurial class is smaller than would be first-best optimal" (Grossman
1984:613).
7 A longer discussion would distinguish between pecuniary and technological externalities. Pecuniary externalities occur through market transactions. They make for market failure, in the
neoclassical sense, only in the presence of economies of scale. Gove1'l1ment coordination can help
to reduce this source of market failure provided the structure of domestic prices is not closely
fixed by the structure of international prices (perhaps because of the investment costs of getting
into exporting). Technological externalities are not transmitted through market transactions. Examples include labor training, when a firm invests in training workers who then join another firm,
or machinery adaptation, when the firm invests in modifications to existing machines which are
then easily copied by others. Technological externalities may be more important causes of neoclassical market failure than pecuniary ones, and may occur independently of capital market imperfections. See Pack and Westphal 1986 and references therein.
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 355
new industries and products. It' may well be that, within limits, price instability has a more adverse effect on growth than price distortions as conventionally defined. A context of deliberately created stability, achieved by riskspreading mechanisms such as protection or subsidies, can facilitate industrial
deepening, export expansion, and political compromises to share adjustment
costs.
Again, a role for industrial targeting can be warranted by the fact of differences between industries in prospects for long-term growth in output, profits,
and wages. Unassisted entrepreneurs may not have either the foresight or the
access to capital to follow long-term potential. Their decisions may lock the
country into specialization in industries with inferior prospects (an issue beyond the scope of comparative advantage theory). Given a world of technical
change, falling cost curves, and differential rates of growth across industries,
it can be rational for a government to select from within the plausible industries those which have high growth potential and to use the powers of government to supplement those of the market in marshalling resources for entry and
successful participation (Scott 1985:95). This means diverting resources from
currently profitable activities into ones that might be fast-growing and/or profitable in the future-which is risky. But any successful large company follows
a strategy of diversifying from currently profitable activities into new ones, on
the assumption that the future will probably be different from the present.
Governments at the national level can aim.to carry through a parallel strategy
of diversification. The scarcer the supply of capital and the higher the entry
barriers of the new industries, the stronger the case for selective assistance.
But can comparative advantage really be modified, made, or achieved in
this way? Traditional theory takes comparative advantage as exogenous,
largely determined by "factor endowments." In a gross way these considerations are still relevant: Burundi should not go in for computer production just
yet. But as Bela Gold says,
Virtually all empirical findings of comparative advantage represent no more than
ex post facto rationalizations of past trade patterns, often reflecting market interventions rather than substantial differentials in efficiency and costs. Moreover,
even the demonstrable comparative advantages prevailing in a given period have
frequently been undermined and even reversed thereafter through determined efforts to advance technologies, shift input requirements, alter transport costs, and
develop new markets. The very identification of current comparative disadvantages often represents the first step in developing means of overcoming them.
(1979:311-12, emphasis added)
William Cline reaches a similar conclusion: "Increasingly, trade in manufactures appears to reflect an exchange of goods in which one nation could be just
as likely as another to develop comparative advantage, and the actual
outcome is in a meaningful sense arbitrary" (l982a:39-40). In place of "ar-
356 CHAPTER 11
bitrary" I would say "subject to strategies of firms and governments." Talk
of "revealed comparative advantage" (measured by the relative preponderance in a country's exports of product x compared to its preponderance in the
trade of the world as a whole) is hence misleading, for the export pattern may
reveal government assistance as much as factor endowments. And factor endowments, it should be remembered, can themselves be arranged on a spectrum from unalterable to alterable, with sunshine at one end and knowledgeable brains at the other. The classic case of Portuguese wine and British sheep
reflects unalterable natural endowments; the modem case of British whiskey
and Japanese electronics reflects human capital build-up, long-term horizons,
and other acquired advantages. Government assistance can create new advantages of the acquired kind, some of which are industry-specific.
The popular belief that governments cannot "make winners" rests on remarkably little empirical research into the record of different governments in
selective industrial promotion. Many governments, especially in small countries, routinely target industrial assistance at specific industries and even at
specific firms, particularly where economies of scale call for a minimum level
of subsidy per firm. Yet we do not have systematic data on the performance
record of different governments which would allow us to distinguish those
with one failure out of four from those with seven failures out of eight. (No
failure is itself failure, because it means that the targeters are not taking
enough risk.) Research on this question has to balance the record of government failure against the record of failure by private business; and examine,
too, what happens to economies where few transformation projects are attempted because the government declines to take an initiative and private business declines to take the risk.
In short, several considerations~conomies of scale and learning, capital
market imperfections, externalities, market instabilities, and differential
growth potential-give grounds for state assistance to industry and to some
industries more than others. 8
8 The question of the degree of selectivity of protection and promotion has hardly begun to be
studied empirically. Pack and Westphal say of Korea: "The set of promoted infants has changed
over time, but it has generally been small at anyone point in time" (1986:94). They prescribe
that "selecti ve intervention must indeed be selective," focused on .. a select few extensive
changes" (1986:118), those that result in distinctly new capabilities and occur through investments with large indivisibilities. On the other hand, Shinohara contrasts the general prescription
for infant industries with Japanese practice. "In general, the nurturing of infant industries is limited to a certain period of time and to a certain number of industries. In Japan, however, these
measures were across the board and applied to almost all industries. Because of the vastly
extended promotion of infant industries and across-the-board encouragement of exports, MITI'S
approach ran counter to the basic principles of modern international economics" (1982:49). One
of the theoretical points at issue is the industry-specificity of the dynamic factors; the more they
.¥e industry-specific the smaller should be the set of promoted industries, while the more they are
-a function of the size of the entire industrial sector the more widely should assistance be spread.
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 357
These arguments for assistance to particular industries are especially relevant to capital goods industries and microelectronics. In medium- and largesized countries, developing a domestic capital goods industry is a necessary
condition for enhancing a country's capacity to develop embodied industrial
innovations. The social costs of not doing so are not fully captured in freemarket prices used to choose between domestic and imported capital goods.
Such prices do not include either the costs of the chronic trade deficits of medium- and large-sized countries that do not produce capital goods or the costs
of the lack of capacity to innovate or adapt technologies associated with the
capital goods industries. The relative absence of a machinery industry means
that an increase in investment becomes an increase in imports. Since much of
the multiplier effect on aggregate demand leaks abroad while the machinery
imports increase productive capacity, the profitability of investments is reduced. Moreover, the relative absence of a capacity to adapt imported technologies means that when domestic demand arises for a new product which
has just appeared in developed country markets (the lag is typically short because those with discretionary purchasing power in developing countries tend
to imitate the consumption patterns of developed countries), it is met by imports. These imports, being in the initial fast-growth-of-demand stage of the
product cycle, tend to grow faster than manufactured exports, which tend to
be in a later and slower-growing stage; and tend to grow all the faster than
agricultural exports, most of which face very slow growth of demand. These
elements cause a tendency toward chronic trade imbalances. The state therefore has a role in directing the sectoral allocation of investment so as to reduce
imports and thereby increase the multiplier effect, check the tendency toward
trade imbalances, and enhance domestic capacity to adapt imported technologies.
Furthermore, over the 1970s and 1980s the development of capital goods
and microelectronics have become intertwined, many innovations taking place
in the course of applying microelectronics to capital goods. National policy
has to playa still bigger role to push domestic producers into the new microelectronics technology than was true of the older electromechanical technology; for entry barriers are typically much bigger (as in the case of numerically
controlled machine tools compared to conventional machine tools, for exampie). But microelectronics constitutes more than just a radical change of technology. It constitutes a change in technoeconomic paradigm, a set of changes
which not only leads to new industries and products but pervades almost every
branch of the economy (Freeman and Perez 1988). The last such change of
paradigm was in the 1930s and 1940s, associated with the utilization of cheap
energy (especially oil). The change underway since the 1970s is associated
See Rodrik (1987) for a theoretical and empirical study of the implications of imperfect competition and economies of scale for trade policy.
358 CHAPTER II
with microelectronics. In the early stages of diffusion of this paradigm "windows of opportunity" open for countries which have already built up a certain
level of infrastructure, industry, and technical knowledge but which have not
made heavy physical and organizational investments in the now superseded
technology system. Newcomers which meet these difficult threshold conditions can catch up with the previous leaders by early entry into the new information technologies (Perez and Soete 1988). A necessary but not sufficient
condition is substantial amounts of government assistance in concentrating
investment and socializing risk. Much of the assistance may have to be in a
leadership rather than a followership mode, because private entrepreneurs are
unwilling to take enough risk, quickly enough, to assure that the new opportunities are taken.
Of course, whether national welfare is actually enhanced by the assistance
depends on the wisdom of the choice of targeted industries and on the effectiveness of implementation. And industrial policies are only one set of factors
on which the competitive success of an industry, or of the country's whole
industrial sector, depends. In the total pattern of causation they are much less
important than the capabilities of the country's private companies. But those
capabilities are themselves able to be augmented by assistance from the public
sector.
We now consider several guidelines about how governments can assist industries to be more competitive. No attempt is made at completeness. The
subjects chosen for discussion meet two criteria: they loom large in East Asian
policies, and they involve some skewing of market processes by changes in
prices or opportunities for exchange.
Prescription 2: Use protection to help create an internationally competitive
set of industries. Two of the things which economists disagree least about are
that protection, whether for restraining the demand for imports or for promoting domestic industries, is always second-best, and that quantitative restrictions (QRS) are always inferior to tariffs. When unrestrained demand for imports leads to balance-of-payment difficulties, the solution is devaluation plus
restrictive expenditure (fiscal and monetary) policy. If for some reason it is
deemed necessary to promote specific industries, credit subsidies should be
used (Corden 1974).
These prescriptions are backed by an impressive body of theoretical reasoning. But once one moves beyond a concern for what is logically consistent
with the theoretical system of neoclassical economics, they are not compelling
guides to decision-making in the real world. As regards devaluation, the first
problem is that experts often disagree by large margins as to what the "desirable" exchange rate should be, not only in developing countries but in industrialized countries as well (notably the United States). Second, even where
~,experts agree that the exchange rate is substantially overvalued, "markets"
often seem to be poor at correcting the imbalances. Third, the policy instru-
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 359
ment is the nominal exchange rate, but there may be no close connection between changes in the nominal rate and changes in the real rate except in the
very short run; and it is the real exchange rate which counts for resource allocation. Fourth, the neoclassical argument recognizes no limits on how far the
exchange rate can be made to fall. But a fall in the real exchange rate means a
fall in the price of non internationally tradable goods and services relative to
the price of tradables. The most important nontradable is labor, so a fall in the
real exchange rate tends in practice to cause a fall in the real wage. Workers
may revolt. More generally, inflexibilities of import-dependent production
processes and consumption patterns may mean that the needed fall in the exchange rate is not possible without disruption of production, inflation, social
unrest, and political conflict, fear of which may induce a well-meaning government to find other methods of maintaining external balance.
The argument to replace protection with credit subsidies as a means of assisting particular industries is also not compelling. First, there can be no presumption that the subsidies needed for infant industries to compete equally
against foreign suppliers would match the finance available. Unless a close
connection is assumed between the revenue-raising capacity of government
and the amount of subsidies needed, the subsidies may exceed the capacity.
Second, the advantages of subsidies cannot be presumed to outweigh the "distortionary" effects of raising revenue through the existing tax system. Third,
protection through tariffs raises revenue in an administratively simple way,
compared to the difficulties of raising revenue through direct taxes; and is
probably no more difficult to administer effectively than a subsidy program
(Luedde-Neurath 1986). Fourth, subsidies are generally a more visible means
of transferring resources and may therefore generate more political conflict
than protection, which transfers resources more invisibly. (Whether this is
desirable depends on whether the pattern of protection makes national sense.)
Finally, insofar as changes in subsidies are more contested politically than
changes in protection, subsidies are unlikely to be changed enough to buffer
short-term external fiuctations.
There are indeed many cases where protection has not had any noticeable
innovation- or investment-enhancing effect (e. g., India). This reflects the failure to integrate protection with a wider industrial policy, or link it to export
performance, or make the quid pro quo conditions credible, or to maintain
macroeconomic stability. If protected producers know that in the foreseeable
future protection will be much reduced or that government will pressure them
to enter export markets, then protection may give them breathing space in
which to undertake the necessary investment and innovation. They can use
higher than normal profits in the domestic market to subsidize their entry into
export markets, practicing discriminatory pricing. The same effect may be induced by awarding import licenses for targeted products only on evidence that
the product could not be obtained from domestic producers within some rea-
360 CHAPTER 11
sonable margin of the import price. Such an "approval" mechanism or "law
of similars" at least forces would-be importers to obtain full information about
domestic supply capability. It also helps to stabilize demand for domestic producers of import substitutes, thereby lowering their risk and encouraging them
to invest enough for economies of scale. But at the same time, the price criterion means that international competitive pressures are brought to bear on
domestic producers, though in a modulated way.
There is, of course, a tension between stimulating demand for nationally
made products by protection (or domestic content requirements, or government procurement) and stimulating the international competitiveness of users
of those nationally made products. Supply-side measures of assistance to the
domestic· producers can help to reduce the conflict. But in any case, it is important that exporters be exempt from most import restrictions, the exemption
being greater the bigger the price and quality differential between imports and ! domestic substitutes. The government can, however, use its import-restricting
ability to encourage users of imported inputs to negotiate with local suppliers
for upgraded production or lower prices in return for guaranteed sales. Repeated across many products, this mechanism can nudge the production structure of the country upwards.
Notice that the mechanism uses QRS rather than tariffs. QRS (and domestic
content requirements) have merit when the acquisition of technological capacity and subsequent adaptive innovation depend on extensive interaction between users and suppliers (Lundvall 1988; Pack and Westphal 1986). However, QRS have the costly consequence of amplifying the volatility of price
signals, because with changes in domestic prices the tariff-equivalent of any
given QR also changes. But where macroeconomic stability prevails, as in East
Asia, this familiar cost of QRS is much less significant. The East Asian experience supports the argument that QRS have lower costs in stable than in unstable macroeconomic conditions.
The desirable degree of import liberalization is much affected by country
size. For most small countries-most of the time and in most industries-a
relatively liberal trade regime is a necessity because of the lack of domestic
economies of scale. Bigger countries have a wider latitude of choice. In general, the wider the latitude of choice, the more the overall degree of trade
freedom should emerge as the result of calculations of the appropriateness of
lowering protection to particular industries, bearing in mind that domestic
competition can substitute for foreign competition, as in Japan, and that domestic competition, even between oligopolists, can be stimulated by government policies. Taiwan and Korea show how liberal trade policies in some industries can be combined with import substitution policies for other industries,
resulting in different incentives to different industries. They also show how a
rapidly industrializing country can soften pressures from its trading partners
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 361
to open its markets or face retaliation, by a judicious combination of camouflage, statements of intent, and real liberalization.
Some developing countries, particularly in sub-Saharan Africa, are unable
to earn enough foreign exchange to cover import demands at any politically
viable exchange rate, because of the limited supply of internationally saleable
products. Here it makes no sense to talk of protection only as a temporary
measure to assist the emergence of infants able within five to ten years to
compete against international competition with no protection. Protection has
to be seen as a part of longer-term measures to gain experience of industry and
large-scale organization. In its absence resources may remain largely unemployed or confined to very small-scale production. The trick is to use such
longer-term protection in a way which does not eliminate all competitive pressures.
In short, import protection is, as neoclassical theory says, a powerful tool.
Like any powerful tool it can be badly used, producing a trade regime full of
inconsistencies. But that is not the end of the story. The East Asian evidencewhose challenge to mainstream trade theory has produced little more than an
elliptical pirouette by way of response-suggests that protection can also be
used in combination with other measures to foster the creation of internationally competitive industries. 9 Where such industries are not on the horizon,
protection can at least help to begin the process of acquiring the capital needed
to make new capital, the knowledge needed to absorb new knowledge, the
skills needed to acquire new skills, and the level of ~evelopment needed to
create the infrastructure and agglomeration economies that make further development possible.
All this suggests an important analytical point, that the international trade
literature is wrong in identifying some policy instruments as unambiguously
better or worse than others without regard to the way those instruments are
administered. QRS administered in a conditional way are not the same as unconditional QRS. Protection may be administered more easily than subsidies,
and so more reliably achieve the intended effects.
Prescription 3: If the wider strategy calls for heavy reliance on trade, give
high priority to export promotion policies. East Asia's fast growth and equitable distribution was undoubtedly helped by the rapid growth of exports. Ex9 It is surprising that Jagdish Bhagwati, one of the most theoretically creative proponents of
nearly free trade regimes, does not attempt to grapple with the effects of Korea's, Taiwan's, and
pre-1970 Japan's protection system on their industrial growth. In writing a book called Protectionism (1988), or in addressing the question of "Is free trade passe after all?" (1989), he might
have been expected seriously to address the empirical association between substantial and selective protection in East Asia and superior industrial perfoJIDance, this being critical evidence and
not just another set of cases. But his oversight does keep him consistent with his own law of
economic miracles: "Economic miracles [Taiwan et al.l are a public good; each economist sees
in them a vindication of his pet theories" (1988:99). For a descriptive account of the East Asian
trade regimes, see Wade 1988b.
362 CHAPTER 11
ports faced less of a demand constraint than output in general; they provided
a channel for technical assistance from buyers; and they gave more scope for
labor utilization than the manufacturing sector as a whole or the existing import-substituting industries in particular. However, export growth is not the
only important reason for fast and equitable growth, and other countries with
different natural resource endowments and larger economic size may be able
to achieve "good" growth and distribution with less reliance on exports
(Adelman 1984; Sen 1981). Indeed, they may not have much choice in the
matter, because Western countries will probably intensify protection to avoid
big (especially China-scale) increases in competing imports from developing
countries.
Where, nevertheless, heavy reliance is to be placed on trade, the government must recognize that successful exporting of manufactured goods to richer
countries is not just a matter of getting the exchange rate right and keeping
labor cheap, even in the absence of protection. 10 This is because many kinds
of manufactured exports to richer countries are only saleable as complete packages meeting all buyer specifications, including packaging, labeling, colors,
raw materials, finishes, and technical specifications. Costs rule out the option
of importing an incomplete or defective package and correcting the defects in
a subsequent stage of manufacturing. Thus, marketing, transmission of information, and quality control tum out to be key activities for export success.
Buyers can supply some of these services; but especially because of the externalities the government also has an important role. The government can arrange for information about foreign markets and about domestic suppliers to
be easily and freely available; it can directly help the promotion of some products (e.g., through trade fairs); and it can help to curb the tendency of firms
without brandnames to compete by producing shoddy goods, spoiling the
country's reputation for other producers. Very importantly, the government
can also inspire producers to seek out export markets as a normal part of their
operations (Keesing 1988).
All this holds even in the absence of protection. If the economy is protected,
cheap labor and a proexport exchange rate are still less likely to be sufficient.
Without quick and automatic access to imported inputs at world market prices,
free of customs duty, quantitative restrictions, and indirect taxes, would-be
exporters will be handicapped in world markets by being forced to pay more
than competitors for the same inputs or by being forced to use inferior domestic substitutes. Since manufactured exports from developing countries are normally sold in intensely competitive markets, producers in a country without a
scheme for duty drawback and relaxation of quantitative restrictions are unlikely to obtain big export orders. Buyers for industrialized countries will sim10 There is disagreement between economists on whether conventional neoclassical trade theory
does or does not support export subsidies. See Bhagwati 1988:95, n.ll.
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 363
ply pass them by. However, even once export sales have near-free trade conditions producers of manufactured goods may still face net incentives to sel!
on the protected domestic market, and exports may still be uncompetitive because the costs of nontradable inputs (especially labor) are raised by demand
for those same inputs from the protected and hence larger-than-otherwise domestically oriented industries. An export sUbsidy scheme may be needed to
make export sales as attractive as domestic market-related sales.
Combining this discussion of export promotion with the preceding discussion of import protection, we see how misleading it is to present import substitution and export promotion as mutually exclusive strategies, as in Anne
Krueger's claim that "export promotion outperforms import substitution"
(1981:5). They are mutually exclusive only if defined to refer to the overall
balance of incentives between domestic and foreign sale. But at the individual
industry level, import-substituting incentives and export-promoting incentives
can be complementary. On the one hand, development of the supply side
through import substitution may be a prerequisite for the demand-side growth
of exports. On the other hand, export growth can be helpful for the further
development of industries that are nearing the limits of import substitution.
Likewise, export promotion in one industry can complement import substitution in another by providing foreign exchange, for example. At anyone time
export promotion and import substitution should coexist, reflecting the different development stages of different industries.
We also see how misleading is the common assumption that policy-induced
neutrality (as when export incentives "counteract" the effects of import controls) is equivalent to free trade. It is not clear how the many kinds of incentives for export- and import-substituting industries can be commensurated (effective protection rates are hardly adequate). It is fairly clear that the structure
ofrelative prices at the time when "neutrality" is achieved reflects the prior
rounds of intervention, and differs from that of an economy with untrammeled
prices and exchanges throughout. Therefore we cannot presume that relative
prices and resource allocations would be unchaflged if the entire array of incentives and protection were eliminated at a stroke.
Prescription 4: Welcome multinational companies. but direct them toward
exports. Multinationals are the primary source of knowledge about technology
and production and an important source of knowledge about marketing. No
country is going to get far in knowledge-intensive manufacturing and services
without their help. Hence the government of a newly industrializing country
should establish attractive policies for foreign capital, whether as subsidiaries,
joint ventures, or licensors. However, foreign firms should be under pressure
to direct their sales toward exports and their input purchases toward local suppliers. For if their products dominate the domestic market the developmental
consequences of the protection system may well be worse than if domestically
owned firms dominate the domestic market.
364 CHAPTER 11
First, with multinationals restricted in terms of their dominance of the domestic market, government efforts to promote the growth and restructuring of
domestic production do not have to go through the multinationals, whose objectives will not wholly coincide with the development of national production
capability. The government is able to use investible funds according to priorities designed to further integrate the domestic market, through having more
influence over the firms that produce for the domestic market than if those
firms were predominantly multinationals. (The multinationals should also be
under foreign exchange controls, for if they are free to move funds in and out
of the country they may start to function as de facto bankers for their domestic
customers and suppliers, eroding the government's own credit policy.) Second, multinationals operating in the domestic market tend to follow marketing
strategies that have little to do with average incomes or traditional consumer
behavior, thereby accentuating income inequalities. By limiting their access
to the domestic market the diversification of goods made available to consumers can be a gradual process geared to the population's purchasing power. In
particular, the most modern of consumer goods, produced chiefly by multinationals, should be restricted to exports until basic needs in food and clothing
have been met-as the Korean government did under Park (Ikonicoff 1985).
Third, export requirements on multinationals not only generate foreign exchange, but also, less obviously, insure that the companies adopt an internationally competitive technology, rather than one which is viable only on the
protected domestic market. However, export requirements may be eased in
return for higher domestic content.
The government should attempt to tie the magnitude of direct foreign investment incentives to either export performance or local content performance.
Application of these principles has to recognize that, given the increasing
•• footlooseness" of much industrial production, the balance between the costs
a country imposes on enterprises and the facilities it provides has to compare
with other countries' If requirements on foreign firms have to be relaxed in
order to attract and keep them, it is important to compensate with discriminatory state support for competing domestically owned firms to prevent them
from being back washed out of existence.
Prescription 5: Promote a bank-basedfinancial system under close government control. A closely regulated bank-based financial system has several advantages in industrializing country conditions. 11 First, it permits higher in-
" For a discussion of "bank-oriented" financial systems (such as Japan and Germany) and
"market bank" systems (United States and Great Britain), see Mayer 1987; Zysman 1983. One
of Mayer's themes is that "the separation between investment and finance, which is the basis of
most existing models, is untenable" (p. iii). My discussion tries to bridge this separation by
showing how a certain type of financial system may affect the "real" economy in developing
~.ountry conditions.
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 365
vestment than would be possible if investment depended on the growth of
firms' own profits or on the inevitably slow development of securities markets.
In a capital market-based system, the decentralized preferences of the public
largely determine the allocation of potential savings into productive investment, financial speculation, or consumption. In a bank-based system, in
which enterprises depend heavily on banks for finance and less on a broad
public of shareholders, the long-term growth preferences of government officials and/or bank executives have more weight. Investment decisions are
hence more insulated from the preferences of the public. Credit can be more
cheaply provided for productive investment, in the context of a long-term approach to the economy's investment activity. In a capital market-based system, on the other hand, government attempts to stimulate investment by tax
cuts and deregulation may have only a modest effect on investment, as in the
economic reforms of President Reagan and Prime Minister Thatcher.
Second, a bank-based system encourages more rapid sectoral mobility and
permits the government to guide that mobility insofar as it can influence the
banks. Even small changes in the discount rate or in concessional credit supply
between sectors can have a significant effect on resource allocation (provided
the use of credit is controlled enough to prevent unlimited fungibility), because the effect of such changes on firms' cash flow position is greater than
where firms have smaller debt/equity ratios. Where the government is trying
to foster key sectors, a bank-based financial system gives it a powerful mechanism for inducing firms to enter sectors they otherwise would not. Where, on
the other hand, capital is allocated mainly in decentralized markets, the government's ability to extend a visible and vigorous hand in the functioning of
the industrial economy is limited, because firms are less susceptible to state
influence (Zysman 1983).
Third, a bank-based system can help to avoid the bias toward short-term
company decision-making inherent in a stock market system. The creditor
needs the borrowing company to do well: it is concerned about the company's
market share and ability to repay loans over the long term, which depend on
how well the company is developing new products, controlling costs and quality, and so on. So these become the criteria which managers are concerned
with, rather than stock market quotations (Johnson 1986; Dore 1985).
The fourth advantage is more directly political. Industrial strategy requires
a political base. Control over the financial system, and hence over highly leveraged firms, can be used to build up the coalitions needed to support the
government's objectives-thus helping to implement the industrial strategy.
Firms are dissuaded from opposing the government by the knowledge that
opponents may find credit difficult to obtain. Of course, such a practice is
easily abused. If it becomes common to allocate credit for "loyalty" rather
than for economic performance or potential the legitimacy of the administra-
366 CHAPTER 11
rive discretion will be impugned. Sparing but well-publicized use may reap
the political gains without the legitimacy costs.
These are four potential advantages of a bank-based, administered-price financial system. However, such a system contains certain imperatives for government action which have far-reaching implications for the government's role
in the economy.
The first is that the government must help to ease the downside risk of debtfinancing. Higher deposit interest rates can increase the flow of financial savings; but at the new rates the private sector may not be prepared to borrow the
savings unless the government intervenes to socialize some of the prospective
private losses. Even if in the short run the savings are translated into loans,
the higher savings and investment made possible by the higher rates may not
be sustainable in the longer run without measures to spread risk. This is because highly indebted (or leveraged) firms are vulnerable to decline in current
earnings to below the levels required by debt repayment, repayments on debt
being fixed (whereas payments on equity are a share of profits). With firms
vulnerable in this way, so are the banks which carry the "nonperforming"
loans. So where debt/equity ratios are high, there is an ever-present danger of
financial instability in the economy:12 bankruptcies, withdrawal of savings, a
fall in real investment, and slower growth. To ease such dangers, firms are
likely to borrow less and banks to lend less than if the government were to
underwrite some of the risks to which lenders and high debt/equity producers
are exposed. If the government does bear some of the risk of private losses,
the supply and demand for loanable funds will be greater, so investment, technical change, and hence growth can be higher.
The need to socialize risk applies especially in the case of highly correlated
risks, to which most firms in major sectors are exposed. So it applies especially to interest rate changes, or major recession, or changes in major export
markets, or political risks. Therefore the impetus for government to shoulder
some of the risks of investment and saving in an economy with high debt/
equity ratios is especially strong in countries which are trade-dependent and!
or under external threat (like Taiwan, Korea, and Japan). The impetus is reinforced in industries where both entry and exit take a long time.
This impetus then leads the government to provide a battery of ways to
reduce the risks of financial instability-not only in the form of deposit insurance and lender-of-Iast-resort facilities, but also in the form of subsidies to
banks imperiled by loan losses, product and credit subsidies to firms in financial difficulties, banks' share-holding in companies, government share-holding in banks and in lumpy projects, and even government ownership of banks.
11 The implications of high debt/equity ratios also depend on profitability at the firm level. In
an economy where profitability is higher and more secure the danger of overall financial instability
is less. The same applies to the implications of high debt/equity ratios for the relationship between
banks and firms. I am indebted to discussions with Frank Veneroso on these matters.
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 367
Government can also, of course, control interest rates and exchange rates to
dampen firms' exposure to market fluctuations in these two important sources
of correlated risk.
The second imperative is for the supplier of credit to become involved with
company management. The supplier of credit may for this purpose be the government (Korea), or the banks (Germany), or some of both (Japan). In any
case, the reason for involvement with management is that the creditor cannot
simply withdraw when a company runs into difficulties by selling the securities in the secondary capital market; the secondary capital markets are too thin.
Given that the "exit" option of the capital market is not available, the alternative is the "voice" option, to try to restructure company management so as
to make it more competitive and to take the long-term view (Hirschman 1970).
Nevertheless the government and/or the banks must, third, develop an institutional capaCity to discriminate between responsible and irresponsible borrowing, and to penalize the latter. Firms which borrow without due commercial caution and run into trouble must not expect the government or the banks
to continue to bail them out (the so-called moral hazard problem). The government must also develop mechanisms of bank supervision to curb the tendency for banks faced with big loan losses to conceal them in the "performing" part of the balance sheet while making even riskier loans in the hope of
getting back enough to offset the losses. This is the path that turns good bankers into bad ones, solvent banks into insolvent ones.
Once market signals are blunted by administered pricing and socialized
risk, the government must, fourth, create a central guidance agency capable
of supplementing market signals by its own signals as to which sectors will be
most profitable--but in a way which allows plenty of scope for private pursuit
of opportunities not seen by the guidance agency.
Finally, the government must maintain a cleavage between the domestic
economy and the international economy with respect to financial flows. Without control of these flows, with firms free to borrow as they wish on international markets and with foreign banks free to make domestic loans according
to their own criteria, the government's own control over the money supply and
cost of capital to domestic borrowers is weakened, as is its ability to guide
sectoral allocation. Speculative inflows seeking exchange rate gains can precipitate accelerating movements in exchange rates, with damaging consequences for the real economy. Uncontrolled outflows can leave the economy
vulnerable to an investment collapse and make it difficult for government to
arrange a sharing of the burden of adjustment to external shocks between the
owners of capital and others; "the others" are likely to be made to take the
burden, with political unrest, repression, and interrupted growth as the likely
result. More generally, foreign exchange controls are needed to intensify the
cycle of investment and reinvestment within the national territory, with outflows only where they can be shown to meet national economic priorities.
368 CHAPTER 11
Otherwise domestic interest rates come to be determined in large part by V. S.
interest rates, and therefore make the economy sUbject to the kind of macroeconomic mismanagement of the V.S. economy seen during the 1980s. Although presented here as just one in a list of several requirements, this cleavage between the domestic financial system and the international financial
system is a prior condition for all the others.
If free markets for foreign exchange and other financial assets were clearly
efficient one might hesitate to recommend such a controlled system. But "belief in the efficiency of the foreign exchange market is a matter of pure faith;
there is not a shred of positive evidence that the market is efficient," concludes
Paul Krugman. Similarly for bonds and stocks: "there is no positive evidence
in favor of efficient markets" (1989:65). On the other hand, the disadvantages
of controis can be partly offset by allowing an unregulated curb market to
operate in the interstices (Biggs 1988)-and perhaps by tying a sizable portion
of subsidized bank credit to export performance. Joseph Stiglitz's new work
on developing country financial systems provides a cogent rationale for- policies broadly in line with those recommended here. He concludes, "the LDCS
should not set their sights on imitating the capital markets of the most developed countries, but rather should adapt themselves to the reality that capital
markets will most likely, if not necessarily, work poorly within their country.
Adopting this view suggests a major redirection of several policies which have
been widely adopted within the third world" (1989:56). He emphasizes more
than I do, however, the difficulties to improving the incentives on government
and large public credit institutions to do a good job in selecting and monitoring
loans.
Prescription 6: Carry out trade and financiaL liberalization graduaLLy, in
line with a certain sequence of steps. Many neoclassical analysts urge largescale and quick liberalization, to get a whole package of reforms in place before opposition builds up. And many urge that comprehensive import liberalization should be carried out before export earnings increase, so as to flush
away the inefficiencies generated by protective barriers and enable a subsequently better response to export demand (Krueger 1978; Snape 1988; La!
1983; Michaely 1988). By contrast, the East Asian experience is consistent
with a prescription for more gradual change and a different sequence. It suggests the following: (1) macroeconomic stabilization should come before trade
liberalization; (2) substantial external financial assistance greatly eases the
transition from stabilization to liberalization; (3) liberalization of imports of
export inputs should come before deprotective competition-providing import
liberalization; (4) import liberalization of the latter type is not a prior condition
for successful exporting; it should follow the growth of exports; (5) successful
exporting requires a large promotional role for public agencies; (6) gradual
trade liberalizations can be sustained; and (7) financial liberalization should
come late in the queue, after a substantial measure of import liberalization
(Sachs 1987; Helleiner 1988; Edwards 1985; Wade 1988b).
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 369
With reference to financial liberalization, our knowledge of its effects in
segmented and imperfect capital markets is thin. Modeling the connections
between the regulated financial markets and the curb market in Korea has generated "unconventional" results from orthodox monetary and interest rate
policies. Higher (regulated) interest rates and monetary restraint led to a serious slowdown in investment and growth, the effects of which exceeded any
positive effects for household savings (van Wijnbergen 1983). Painful experience with rapid and far-reaching financial liberalization in the Southern Cone
countries of Latin America has bred a new respect for government supervision
and control of the domestic financial system, and caution about lifting external
capital markets controls. These results support the gradual approach to domestic and external financial liberalization adopted in East Asia (Helleiner
1988; Mayer 1987; Krugman 1989).
More generally, the gradualness of economic liberalizations in all three
countries further undermines the view that if only the government of a developing country shrinks from influencing prices or exchanges, it too can expect
much improved economic performance. The East Asian liberalizations were
gauged to the competitiveness of domestic industry, which was itself promoted by preceding and simultaneous industrial policies. Without them, letting prices work would have been like pushing on a piece of string.
There is also a political case for gradualism, which should be weighed
against the political argument for quick and deep liberalization to preempt
opposition. Liberalization typically involves changes-removal of food subsidies, for example-whose costs affect the general public widely and directly
but whose benefits are more concentrated and slower to appear. If several such
policies are introduced at once and entail major rather than incremental
change, they can be expected to generate opposition from many interest
groups, including some whose support is important for the regime's survival.
They therefore carry high stakes for the incumbent political leaders, all the
more so when the government is insecurely legitimated. Gradual introduction
of the reforms, with some sequencing and camouflaging of who gets the costs
and benefits, can provide less fuel for opposition organization and thereby
make sustained implementation more likely. In the general case, this seems as
plausible a scenario as that of the neoclassicals. 13
In considering issues of liberalization we need to make a distinction between shrinkage of the public sector and reduced state capacity to manage the
J3 Indira Ghandi' s post· 1980 government carried out significant economic liberalization without drawing sharp political reaction partly because she made the changes look like marginal,
"technical" ones. Her Son and successor, by boldly proclaiming a decisive shift of development
strategy to a liberal model, aroused such widespread opposition from groups on whom the Congress depended for votes as to force a drastic slowdown in the liberalization. However, in the
early period Rajiv Ghandi's govemment did successfully introduce a number of liberalizing policies-those which "were brought about quietly, without much fanfare, as seemingly technical
changes in a piecemeal fashion" (Kohli 1989:314).
370 CHAPTER II
market. The size of the public sector, in terms of employment, share of GOP,
and other such measures, is not closely associated with state capacity to manage the market. 14 Indeed, shrinkage of the fonner-which would be called
"liberalization" in the gross way the term is generally used-may help to
expand the latter; and the latter is what counts.
The argument for economic liberalization-whether in trade, finance, or
other spheres-also needs to address the question of what kinds of private
sector groups will gain from the change. It cannot be assumed that they will
wish to be entrepreneurial investors rather than lUXUry consumers. Nor can it
be assumed that they will wish to place limits on the arbitrary actions of the
state and discipline the state to provide effective services. Liberalization may
lead to the capture of economic power by less accountable cliques around the
power-holders, Marcos-style. The analytical dichotomy between "state" and
"economy" can lead us to overlook the point that the same people or groups
may have feet planted finnly on both sides of the divide, in which case a
shrinkage of the state and expansion of the private sector may further remove
economic power fonnerly in the hands of the state from some degree of accountability. It may further erode a "center" -a cohesive organizational
structure-where collective interests can be articulated and followed.
These are six broad economic prescriptions supported by the experience of
Taiwan, Korea, and Japan. But we must note another lesson to do with differences rather then similarities. While the three East Asian states all governed
the market, they used somewhat different methods for doing so. Taiwan used
large upstream public enterprises and selected foreign finns to provide "unbalanced" pushes in certain sectors, arms-length incentives to steer the response of myriad small downstream firms, and stable prices and real effective
exchange rate. Korea used huge private business groups as the spearheads,
steering them with massive credit subsidies and more direct cajoling (recently
switching to more of a negotiation mode). It obtained more of its technology
under license than through direct foreign investment, and sacrificed some
macroeconomic stability for faster industrial transformation. Japan, which already had huge private business groups in place in the 1930s, pioneered the
route that Korea was later to follow, except that consultative decision-making
procedures linking government and business were in place from much earlier
on. So there is more than one way to govern the market effectively.
IMPROVING STATE EFFECTIVENESS
My argument is that a necessary but not sufficient condition for more rapid
industrialization is state deployment of a range of industrial promotion policies, including ones to intensify the growth of selected industries within the
national territory. This is not to say that effectiveness increases with the sheer
14 See chapter I, n.l2.
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 371
amount of intervention, nor that it increases the more the state imposes its will
on society, ignoring other groups. State effectiveness is a function ofthe range
of options, given by the number and force of policy instruments, and the flexibility with which those policy instruments are used. Flexibility means that the
capacity to intervene, as given by the number and force of policy instruments,
is used to varying degrees, more in some industries than in others at anyone
time, and more in one industry at some times than at others, always with an
eye on the costs of interventions in political as well as economic terms. In
particular, high effectiveness requires the flexibility to withdraw assistance
from industries as they become internationally competitive, and the ability not
to intervene in some industries at all in the interests of concentrating assistance
and limiting costs. Behind these proximate determinants of effectiveness are
others of a more organizational and political kind. First is the competence and
coherence of the central economic bureaucracy. Second is the degree to which
political authority is institutionalized. Third is the connection between the central bureaucracy and other major economic interests, especially the owners
and managers of capital. We now consider four more prescriptions to do with
these organizational and political determinants of state effectiveness. Again,
the prescriptions are rooted in what East Asian governments actually did.
Prescription 7: Establish a "pilot agency" or "economic general staff"
within the central bureaucracy whose policy heartland is the industrial and
trade profile of the economy and its future growth path. For an industrial policy to be effective one or two agencies should steer the formulation and application of the policy instruments. Taiwan, Korea, and Japan have all used the
"few agencies" model, in contrast to the "many agencies" model of the
United States and Great Britain.
The pilot agency should have a fairly small staff (Japan's MlTI had only
about two thousand in the 1960s). It should be in a position to recruit from
among the best and the brightest. Once a competitively selected economic
bureaucracy acquires a reputation for attracting the best and brightest, the system develops a momentum of its own. It continu€1s to attract such people (even
at much lower salaries than the private sector) because selection is the stamp
of outstanding talent. Its personnel need to be motivated by the belief that what
they are doing promotes the national welfare. A sense of national mission,
combined with a meritocratically based esprit de corps, can motivate the central bureaucracy to use its powers in line with national goals, prOViding a substitute for the motivational force of profits in private firms. A vigorous national
press, free to criticize the economic bureaucracy (even if not the political leaders) can help to keep its actions in line with the public interest. The conflict
between life-time employment and up-to-date technical and managerial
knowledge can be moderated by using parabureaucratic task forces to complement in-house capabilities. The more the government intends to intervene in a
leadership rather than a followership mode, the more important are the staffing, motivation, authority, and responsibilities of the pilot agency.
372 CHAPTER II
The pilot agency should be concerned with fonnulating operational goals,
such as diversification of industries, diversification of markets, reduced dependence on raw material imports, and greater employment in certain industries; and with analyzing how various policies affect these goals. It should
think of itself as a strategic oligopolist, scrutinizing the actions of rival governments and taking account of those actions and reactions in framing its policies for investment, trade, and technology.
It should have some power of implementation rather than devolve all concern for implementation to the ministries. It should focus on certain key industries at anyone time, more or less ignoring the rest; but should situate
policies for these industries within an analysis of the whole economy, bringing
multiple policy instruments to bear on them. This can be done without detailed
quantitative targets for investment and output for particular industries, which
are only likely to distract from the more substantive business of fonnulating
the broad vision of the appropriate directions for growth and choosing the
specific industries to be promoted. Multibusiness, multinational corporations
undertake a broadly similar type of strategic (rather than comprehensive) planning as a matter of course, and their techniques can, with modifications, be
extended to multi-industry, multi market countries.
In addition to the organizational factors considered above, the effectiveness
of such an agency is related to the decision criteria it uses. One of the great
merits of using export perfonnance is its simplicity and clear connection to
competitiveness. It can be used to make a first judgment on assistance to firms
or industries; those that are doing well in export markets will be treated more
favorably than those which are not, other things being equal. When a country
is pursuing a domestic market-based strategy, particularly one which is led by
agriculture, simple and sensible decision criteria are more difficult to find
(Pack and Westphal 1986). Above all, one must deemphasize criteria that, for
ease of measurement, focus on inputs, not on outputs.
The activities of such an agency are likely to be uncongenial to economists
trained to believe that targeting by officials will generally fail. That is one
good reason for curbing the number and influence of economists in the industrial policy-making process, as was done in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan. The
other reason is that neoclassical economics has little to say about the issues
raised by the present shift of technoeconomic paradigm, of how to exploit the
opportunities opened by the new information technologies (Dosi, et al. 1988).
Of course, in Cuba, North Korea, the Soviet Union, China, and other centrally
planned economies, the more neoclassically trained economists the better.
Prescription 8: Develop effective institutions of political authority before
the system is democratized. The class structure of many developing countries
implies a cruel choice between faster economic development and well-defended civil and political rights. Power and wealth are often concentrated in
groups engaged in socially unproductive activities (including renting out of
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 373
land, money-lending, exploitation of bureaucratic or military office}. Groups
based on industry must grow on the margins of power, perhaps as part of a
coalition of sections of the state bureaucracy and sections of the military. Often the rise of this" growth coalition" is attended by conflict as it tries to
displace groups with real coercive power, capable of taking the law into their
own hands. It may try to harness a popular political movement using nationalism or revolt against exploitative class relations as a rallying cry. Once it
can influence state power, it has to use that influence to shape a social structure
which is conducive to wealth accumulation through productive investment.
Most likely this will require some curtailment of the political and civil rights
of those who oppose the changes, and of the powers of democratically elected
legislatures (Huntington 1968).
The argument in favor of such a state is uncomfortable to those (including
myself) who cherish the civil and political freedoms of North American and
Western European countries-especially when "democracy," more than any
other term in political discourse, now generates such a universal hurrah. "It
has been difficult for me to comprehend how free people can choose tyranny
for others," declares A. M. Rosenthal, former executive editor of the New
York Times. "There is for me only one question that really matters about any
government: does it allow political freedom? Does it permit its citizens to
breathe and think and talk and write as free people?" (1986:23). He goes on
to say that "the apologists for tyrannies argue that economic progress has to
come first, and that democracy is really too expensive a way of achieving it.
This is said in all seriousness, as if there were evidence that despotism somehow is more efficient than freedom. The exact opposite seems so obviously
true " (p. 24). (Rosenthal includes the Park and Chun regimes of Korea
as tyrannies, and would presumably so call the Nationalist government of Taiwan.)
Rosenthal's Manichean assertions notwithstanding, the balance of argument and evidence seems to me to point the other way. People who live in
societies where, for a whole century or more, they have been able to see "freedom of opinion" as about whether editors get sent to jailor not, find it hard to
comprehend the priorities of people in societies where freedom is also restrained by fear of the assassin's bullet and fear of being thrown off one's land
by trumped-Up suits and corrupt judges. In such societies the priority is to
institutionalize a system of order before it is democratized-to move from a
system where the press is controlled by people with wealth and private armies
to one where it is controlled by the state, before reaching one where it is controlled by people with wealth but without private armies.
The executive branch needs to be stronger than the legislative branch, to
"rule" while the legislature "reigns." An elected legislature is likely to be
directed less by a view of the common good than by, in Adam Smith's phrase,
"the clamorous importunity of partial interests" (1775:438). A state in which
374 CHAPTER 11
the legislature is strong relative to the executive will find it difficult to hold the
line against unbalanced increases in consumption at the expense of investment, and difficult to direct government assistance to uses which can meet a
national interest test rather than a clamorous importunity test. Conversely,
where the executive is relatively strong, there is a better chance that policies
will not careen from side to side because of frequent turnover in power. This
makes for a more stable business environment, facilitating longer-term corporate investment. And it helps the bureaucracy to oversee the operation of
the economy.
Historically, individual property rights, constitutional restraints .on the
state, 'and the rise of the bourgeoisie occurred before the advent of mass democracy (Huntington 1984). Both Taiwan and Korea now provide support for
the proposition that the stability of a new democracy depends upon the development of broad-gauged political institutions prior to the expansion of political participation. As we noted, they were in the middle of a rights ranking of
middle-income countries in the early 1970s; Taiwan was in the same position
in the early 1980s while Korea had fallen a little lower. As of the late 1980s,
they are making a transition to stable and partially democratic systems, with
the prospect of more democratization to come. Japan, of course, has had much
better defended rights since World War H. But Japan's primary industrial revolution took place during the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, at
which time its political and civil rights were quite restricted, its government
distinctly authoritarian and oligarchic. For the past thirty years Japanese voters
have gone to the polls with slimmer expectations that the result could be a
change of government than in any other industrialized democracy; and the
representatives whom they elect have had less influence on the major decisions
affecting the national welfare than in any other industrialized democracy.
Large cross-sectional studies of developing countries show that democratic
regimes tend to grow more slowly than authoritarian ones. Robert Marsh, using a sample of ninety-eight developing countries and several development
indicators for the period from 1960 to 1970, concludes that "political competition/democracy does have a significant effect on later rates of economic
development; its influence is to retard the development rate rather than facilitate it" (1979:244). Erich Weede, using a different method 'and a different but
also large sample of countries, concludes in part that' 'political democracy looks
like a major barrier to economic growth in those countries where the state
strongly interferes in the economy" (1983:312).15 But there is also probably
J~ See also Adelman and Morris 1967: HUntington and Dominguez 1975. Dick (1974) finds the
reverse relationship. For a useful discussion, see Kohli 1986. Interventionist governments in
Weede's analysis had revenue equal to or greater than 20 percent of GDP in 1965 at all income
levels. He finds thirty-four such cases (thirty-five for one regression). He uses Bollen'S (1980)
classification of countries as democratic or authoritarian in 1965 (excluding the centrally planned
economies). The methodological difficulties of establishing a causal connection between regime
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 375
more variation in the performance of authoritarian regimes compared to democratic ones at similar per capita incomes. some having mediocre to calamitous results. Many authoritarian governments do not give high priority to economic development. being preoccupied with the task of excluding most of the
population from power. 16 As per capita income approaches $4,000, the economic advantages of continued restrictions of civil and political rights---of
continued consolidation of authority in the hands of the state-are probably
offset by the costs of growing conflict, weak legitimacy, and overburdened
state decision-making. This, at least, is a possible interpretation of the fact
that over the 1980s there have been virtually no noncommunist countries at or
above this income level without fairly competitive political systems. Singapore is an exception, and Taiwan would have been had it not initiated democratic reforms in 1986.
Prescription 9: Develop corporatist institutions as or before the system is
democratized. State effectiveness depends on the coherence of state policies,
which is difficult to maintain when important parts of the state are beholden to
sectoral, ethnic, or regional interests. Effectiveness is therefore a function of
the degree of insulation (or "autonomy") from the surrounding social structure. Insulation is a function of, among other things (1) officials' dependence
on the state for their income, not on interest groups; (2) officials' expertise,
which gives them grounds for asserting their own preferences for state action
against those of interest groups; and (3) the extent to which the nation faces a
threat to "national interests" from other states, in response to which nons tate
groups are likely to confer substantial autonomy on state officials.
Even in a highly pluralist regime some bureaucratic insulation is conferred
by these conditions. In an authoritarian regime the insulation can be much
greater because the coalitional basis of the state is narrower. But insulation of
central officials from pressures in the wider society also carries costs. It may
erode feedback on economic conditions at the point of production and sale,
and may remove a potentially strong basis for the formation of a consensus on
the dominant factors influencing the course of the economy and the order of
type and economic growth are fonnidable; see Hicks and Patterson (1989) and the papers to which
they are responding. The gross categories of authoritarian and democratic regimes are too crude
to capture some important aspects of civil and political rights. In particular, by focusing on the
freedom or lack of freedom to choose rulers they miss the greater importance in the lives of
ordinary people of having power to shape the rules which govern the immediate or local aspects
of their lives. Perhaps some authoritarian regimes with strong national-level executives neverthe-
-less grant or tolerate considerable latitude in the choice of local rules.
16 Dick (1974: table 1) provides some evidence of greater dispersion in the perfonnance of
authoritarian regimes. One might relate the dispersion not only to goals (exclusion, economic
development, etc.), but also to the type of military they are associated with-the swashbuckling,
tribute-raising kind or the strategic-planning, military-engineering kind. In the decade following
the mid-1970s most Latin American countries have swung from authoritarian to partially democratic regimes (GastiI1986).
376 CHAPTER II
socioeconomic priorities. Even in the most centralized government, the course
of the economy is influenced by the decisions of many separate agenciesdecisions about the exchange rate, tariffs, interest rates, availability of capital,
wages, public expenditure, public borrowing, taxes, and more. Any attempt
at comprehensive control from a single point would overstrain the government's information capacity and power. Without a roughly common view
about decision premises, national economic policy decisions are unlikely to
achieve the degree of coherence needed for their overall success. Moreover,
when the thinking classes are wholly familiar with a certain range of ideas and
assumptions about the longer-term future there is a base of legitimacy for government-sponsored measures with long-term payoffs. This base of legitimacy
is especially important when some will be losers.
But such a consensus is always fragile, vulnerable to the whims of important interest groups because of changes in circumstances, priorities, or evaluations. A corporatist structure·? to represent a limited set of major economic
interest groups-and thereby also to channel the demands placed upon the
state--<:an help to insure acceptance of negotiated outcomes. It can help to
mediate the uneasy tension between unrestricted market forces and social
peace, buffering the costs of economic adjustments to external market changes
while allowing adjustments to occur (Ruggie 1982). It does so by facilitating
reciprocity between big firms, government, and perhaps unions, \8 in which
government help is made conditional on stipulated performance by the other
parties; and by facilitating the use of state authority to steer groups away from
hostile strategies that yield the worst outcomes in Prisoner's Dilemma situations. However, such arrangements are difficult to sustain where the idea of
the public or national interest is used primarily as a cover for advancing private, class, or ethnic interests, where a core meaning shared by all the parties
is lacking.
The only evidence I know of on the economic performance of corporatist
17 In a corporatist structure. the state chaners a limited number of major economic interest
groups, granting them a near monopoly of representation. In authoritarian regimes of the common
garden variety, the leaders control and appeal to the people directly, without this intermediating
structure of representation. And pluralist regimes differ from both in having a geographical rather
than functional basis of representation, and in having' 'free trade" in interest group access to the
state. I. Inclusion of labor is obviously desirable in principle. But note that if labor exclusion is part
of a set of arrangements which generate high-speed growth, workers are protected to some extent
by high labor demand. Labor exclusion also gives a government more room to maneuver when
austerity comes, and that latitude can be used to restore fast growth more quickly (compare Mexico and Taiwan). But the more mature an economy becomes the less likely is economic growth to
be sufficiently fast to meet the norm3.J aspirations for economic security. It is then of the first
importance that the institutional arrangements made to provide security do not erode the pressure
on people to work hard or convert security guarantees into obstacles to adjustment. The key is to
build up labor commitment, so that effort is not based simply on an exchange of effort for pay.
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 377
regimes comes from already wealthy and democratic countries, whose corporatism is of the "social corporatist" type. Here peak associatiol)s have more of
a policy-initiating role than under' 'state corporatism." The evidence suggests
that countries with social-corporatist arrangements (such as Austria, Norway,
Switzerland, and Sweden) have enjoyed above-average incomes and economic growth, with lower inflation and unemployment, than pluralist countries. In particular, those countries with arrangements for centralized bargaining, politically dominant social democratic parties, and centralized unions,
tended to weather the international economic crises of the 1970s better than
others. Pluralist countries like the United States and Great Britain, which tolerate raw adversarial outcomes between economic interest groups, have been
less successful in adjusting to these crises. 19 But this conclusion cannot readily
be extended to cover corporatism in developing country conditions, about
which there is little evidence. I expect that state corporatist regimes vary more
in their economic perfonnance than pluralist ones. Salazar's Portugal and Per6n's Argentina, both state corporatist, had dismal records, while Taiwan and
Korea have had exceptionally good ones (also Japan in its extreme state corporatism of 1940-41). The variation may be closely connected to rulers' objectives. In East Asia a shared sense of the external vulnerability of the nation
has helped to concentrate the rulers' minds on perfonnance-enhancing measures as a means of their own survival.
The Taiwan case shows an interesting variant of state corporatist arrangements. Fonnal industrial associations are weak, as we saw; but there is plenty
of communication between government officials and finns of an infonnal, often dyadic kind. Industrial Development Bureau officials often spend several
days a month visiting industry associations and finns in "their" industry, for
example. 20 These and other means of keeping in touch with finn-level facts
are vital if the government is to intervene to promote specific industries,
whether as leader or follower.
Prescription 10: Make piecemeal reforms even in soft states so as to create
an institutional configuration better able to support a modest industrial policy.
Suppose one agrees that governed market policies can improve on the economic results of free or simulated free market policies. Whether such gains
are realized depends on the existence of certain organizational arrangements,
as just indicated. When such arrangements are not already in existence, administrative and political reforms can create them. But these refonns cannot
be simply willed into existence, and their effects take a long time to come
19 Wilensky 1981; Schmitter 1981; Schmidt 1982; Wilson 1985:110; cf. Zeigler 1988:chapters
3--4. I have not examined the Latin American evidence. U.S. and British economic performance
has improved during the 1980s in terms of many aggregate indicators, though market share in
many of their high-technology industries continues to erode.
20 For a South Korean example of little formal communication combined with abundant informal communication, see Wade 19&2a:54-56, 90.
378 CHAPTER II
through. Given this, one might argue that-even accepting the potential gains
of governed market policies-most states should move toward free market
policies as fast as possible, on grounds that softer states can sustain these policies more easily than governed market ones.
Paul Krugman, for one, argues that even though recent work in trade theory
provides a rationale for an activist trade strategy in certain conditions (which
are, however, unlikely to apply to developing countries), the gains may not be
large and the strategy is difficult to implement because of its vulnerability to
hijacking by special interest groups. Hence, he says, free trade rules are best
for" a world whose politics are as imperfect as its markets" (1987: 143). Instead of political factors being blamed for the inability of governments to follow economically rational free trade policies, political factors are now brought
in to say why free trade remains politically best even after it is shown to be
not always economically best (Helleiner 1988). This is but a special case of
the "practical optimality" of free markets. Even if free markets can be shown
to be suboptimal according to some ideal allocation system, they are the
method which produces the least inefficient resource allocation in practice, the
argument runs. The alleged alternative, administrative allocation, will produce worse results because it is not subject to anybody's bottom-line constraint.
There is something to be said for this argument. The image of the highsalaried official who knocks off to play golf at 4:30 leaving a pile of files on
his desk and then, when he gets to your application three weeks later, casually
says no, is more outrageous than that of the wheeler-dealer entrepreneur who
is continually creating monopolies, rigging prices, making false advertising,
and so on. But proponents of this argument fail to explain why, if vested interests are strong enough to defeat sensible selective interventions, they will
not also be strong enough to distort markets and defeat free trade. Free trade
is not self-enforcing. Vested interests seek to maintain the structures in which
their interests are vested, rent-seekers seek to preserve the conditions that create rents. Karl Polanyi reminds us that Adam Smith's "natural propensity to
truck and barter" had not sufficed to produce free markets in England. "The
road to the free market was opened and kept open by an enormous increase in
continuous, centrally organized and controlled interventionism" (1957:140).
A passionate exponent of free trade agrees that "a courageous, ruthless and
perhaps undemocratic government is required to ride roughshod over special interest groups" that stand in the way (Lal 1983:33). In practice, then,
free trade may be no easier to sustain than sensibly managed trade. (One wonders, incidentally, what fraction of GDP the United States spends on competition policies, including not only the cost of the relevant government agencies
but also the "chilling" effect of antitrust legislation in inhibiting agreements
which might have been beneficial, as well as the transaction cost of the legions
ofdawyers involved in every move.)
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 379
Even in the context of a relatively soft state it should be possible to institute
higher levels of effectiveness in limited parts of the state. It should be possible
for the state's industrial policies effectively to do more than put a seal of approval on what the private sector would have done anyway. By bringing to the
negotiations its own sense of the appropriate direction of the economy, and by
paying for more rather than less of the costs of a new project which fits that
direction, it can still impart a directional thrust. The organizational arrangement might take the form of a pilot agency which, though lacking the implementation power OfMITI or Taiwan's Industrial Development Bureau, still has
some statutory power which makes it necessary to the making of policy, so
that it can force its long-term perspective into pluralistic bargaining. One
would need to insure that appointment to the senior positions of such an
agency is by merit criteria; that the incumbents cannot be rotated in and out
according to the sway of factions or money; that the standard operating procedures allow the agency to stick to a purpose, so as to deal with surprises and
opposition in line with enduring goals; and that it has secure funding.
Elsewhere in the economic bureaucracy effectiveness and responsiveness
can be improved by several kinds of measures. There are the standard institution-building ones, including more financial resources, higher status, and bigger supervisory infrastructure. But more interesting are ones which attempt to
introduce more market-like features into bureaucratic incentive systems, while
remaining incremental in nature and not requiring sweeping changes in order
to have some effect (Lamb 1982; Murray 1989). These include ways of changing internal incentives and options, such as decentralizing managerial accountability within bureaus or agencies, inducing competition between sections
within a bureau or between agencies and parabureaucratic task forces, establishing more performance-based salary and promotion rules, creating a super
cadre with better pay and more exacting performance standards than in the
normal civil service, establishing public management accounting systems
which record output and performance as well as costs, and developing a random-check performance auditing capability. by senior managers. These
changes can be complemented by ones which seek to put more market-like
pressure on the bureaucracy from outside, such as publicizing performance
targets and rates of achievement, organizing would-be beneficiaries into industrial associations and turning over much of the high-cost "retailing" end
of industrial service delivery to industry associations or private firms. Shifting
from "control by ownership" to "control by contract" can both improve
work incentives and reduce the administrative burden on the state. The state
retains control over a key segment of a service operation while subcontracting
out the other parts. Taiwan and Korea show how some of these ideas can be
operationalized (for Korea, see Wade 1982a).
These organizational requirements are no doubt difficult to meet in many
states, even if focused on only a small part of the civil service. But they are
380 CHAPTER 11
not of the kind that ask elephants to fly; they should not cause us to say that
outside the configuration of a hard state political reality dictates a close approximation to free market policies as the best practical way forward. We tend
to assume, wrongly, that the ills of public bureaucracy are intrinsic to this
generic type of organization, and therefore are inclined to embrace "the market" as the preferred alternative. In fact, many of those ills are features of one
particular-though predominant-model of organization found in the corporate as well as the public sector. This "mechanical" model, characterized by
elaborate specialization of tasks and standardized procedures, by extended
chains of command and written communications, is now being radically reformed in the corporate sector of the West, so as to create organizations better
adapted to the exigencies of the new information and production technologies
(Hoffman 1989). These new forms of corporate organization can provide experience for new forms of public administration.
The current economic difficulties, and budgetary pressures in particular, are
making many governments more prepared to tackle difficult institutional issues than would be the case in more normal times; they are running out of
alternatives. At the same time, the current conditions in the world economy
increase the potential advantages of pursuing GM policies-to modulate the
volatility of the world economy on the domestic economy, to help domestic
firms compete internationally in the face of increasingly fierce international
competition, and to force an early entry into information technologies. Firms
whose governments decline to provide assistance may relocate, or they may
resort to squeezing labor costs and intensifying work practices in order to
avoid losing market share, enlisting the power of the state to help them do so.
This higher premium on GM policies raises the advantages of undertaking the
organizational improvements needed to support them.
In any case, whether government seeks to promote particular industries or
seeks only to make all markets freer, it is likely to have to make organizational
changes along these lines. Even a government committed to free trade must
be purposeful, must have a system of policy management that recognizes the
effects of interactions among its own activities, and must be able to insure that
desired responses are forthcoming from the commitment of public resources
used as side-payments to those who would otherwise block market processes
(Heclo 1986). Free trade policies are no means of escape from the need to
improve the capabilities of governments.
The United States is a telling example. Lacking these capacities, the U.s.
government uses leaky protectionist instruments as much as most other industrialized economies. But its departures from free trade are largely a case-bycase response to domestic political pressures rather than being part of a strategy for gestating or nurturing future competitive industries. With no one being
required to explain or defend what is being done, its industrial policies remain
ad hoc and implicit. Indeed, the philosophical repugnance against government
LESSONS FROM EAST ASIA 381
involvement in industrial promotion is such that the government lacks both
detailed knowledge of industries and analytical capacity to select appropriate
actions. If an industry is in trouble, the government is meant to become involved only when trade is said to be "unfair" or when national security is
involved; otherwise, whether the industry becomes more competitive, moves
offshore, or goes out of existence is a matter of government indifferencebecause the market outcome is assumed to be best. This repugnance is translated into and then confirmed by organizational incompetence at carrying out
concerted industrial policies. The personnel policies of the federal government
compound the problem, for they are designed to attract (in the approving
words of a former associate director of the Office of Personnel Management)
"competent people, not the best and most talented people," who should be
encouraged to migrate to the private sector, "the true vehicle for prosperity"
(cited in Allison 1989).
In these several ways, the United States is a model of what developing
countries should avoid. Yet the thinking of most of the international aid community, including USAlD and the World Bank, is profoundly shaped by American conceptions of the role and competence of government. And the political
meta-assumptions of neoclassical prescriptions are calibrated to those same
ideas. All the more reason for developing countries to study the East
Asian experience to see how government and capitalism are arranged where
economic development has been a top national priority for decades. And all
the more reason for economists to accept the challenge of constructing a theoretical rationale for the non-neoclassical East Asian facts. When the next
Wealth of Nations comes to be written, it will look more favorably upon governing the market. The first Adam Smith would surely approve. It was he who
warned from his study of the history of astronomy, "The learned give up the
evidence of their senses to preserve the coherence of the ideas of their imagination" (in Lindgren 1967:77).
Comments
Post a Comment