cbdc adoption
If potential central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) are to achieve their policy goals, they would need to be
adopted by users and accepted by merchants. This report outlines the considerations for central banks in
designing a CBDC that might fulfil user needs both now and in the future. Learning from past payment
innovations, considering the features most valued by users, investigating incentives for adoption and carrying
out consultations could all play an important role in CBDC design. The next steps for this work will be to
continue research on the impact user requirements and financial stability safeguards on system design, and
the range of approaches to public engagement and consultation on CBDC.
1. Introduction and general overview
A central bank digital currency (CBDC) would need to be adopted and used if it is to fulfil public policy
goals that motivate its issuance.1 Integral to achieving adoption and use of a general purpose CBDC in a
jurisdiction would be understanding and serving current and future user needs in a fast-changing
payments landscape. This report examines what drives user adoption of digital payment services,
referencing the use-cases and design choices envisaged for CBDC. Without being prescriptive or precise
about a specific level of adoption that might ensure success of a CBDC project, this report presents issues
that jurisdictions may wish to consider in their own evaluations.
Key messages:
• CBDC adoption would likely be driven by its future usefulness to users and acceptance by
merchants. Central bank money is the safest form of money available. Yet beyond security, other
valuable features of CBDC could include lower cost to consumers and merchants, offline
payments, a higher level of privacy in comparison to commercial options and multiple
accessibility features.
• A CBDC would need to anticipate the needs of future users and incorporate related
innovations. Central banks might accommodate evolving user needs by designing a flexible core
system, supporting a diverse ecosystem of intermediaries delivering choice, competition and
innovation. As payments become increasingly integrated into digital living, a CBDC available to
innovators could combine innovative features into a single product in a new and unique way.
• Strategies for CBDC adoption would need to be tailored to the diverse economic structures
and payment landscapes in individual jurisdictions, but experience points to some common
factors. Specifically, adoption may be more successful if it fulfilled unmet user needs, achieved
network effects, and were implemented with the use of existing, accessible technology and
infrastructure (eg at the point of sale). Additional measures that some jurisdictions might consider
for a potential CBDC adoption strategy include the use of CBDC by public sector authorities,
requiring some minimum level of acceptance and supporting future payment needs. Not all
strategies would be desirable in all jurisdictions.
• A CBDC adoption strategy in a fast-changing payments landscape would require balancing
the needs of the majority of consumers with reaching smaller parts of the population.
Different users and needs would need to be defined and addressed in the system’s design. The
analysis of specific market segments through user personas and stories could provide an
important method for investigating user needs and designing informative consultations with
prospective end-users.
1 Central bank digital currency is a digital form of central bank money that is different from balances in traditional reserve or
settlement accounts ie a digital payment instrument, denominated in the national unit of account (Group of central banks
(2020)).
2 Central bank digital currencies: user needs and adoption
• Further exploration will involve considering how financial stability safeguards might allow the
CBDC adoption needed to meet public policy objectives and user needs, how user requirements
could impact system designs, and the approach to public consultation and communications on
CBDC
Section 2 provides some context on CBDC adoption. Section 3 then identifies key features of the
experience with implementation of previous payments innovations (both successful and failed) and the
lessons that may be drawn for CBDC. Section 4 then examines user needs followed by a discussion on
strategies for designing a CBDC. The last section concludes.
2. Context on CBDC adoption
For a discussion of CBDC adoption, there are two important contextual elements from the preceding report
published by this group of central banks and the BIS (Group of central banks (2020)).
First, for the central banks contributing to this report, the common motivation for exploring a
general purpose CBDC is its use as a means of payment. “Use” in this report should be understood in this
context. Adoption of CBDC as a means of payment would likely present the most value for public policy
objectives.
Second, without continued innovation and competition to drive efficiency in a jurisdiction’s
payment system, users may adopt other, less safe instruments or currencies, potentially leading to
economic and consumer harm. If user needs emerge in the future, unserved by safe payment instruments,
the chance of this risk materialising arguably increases.
CBDCs that support innovation and competition may play a role in supporting future user
requirements for payment services. Digital payments are already rapidly changing in response to an
increasing integration into evolving digital services (BIS (2020)). It is likely that these evolutions will
continue and catalyse an even broader diversity of novel use cases and payments requirements than today.
Central banks may therefore need to consider current and possible future user demands in their CBDC
system designs, understanding where new technologies might be harnessed (eg programmable money)
and through encouraging innovation and competition among intermediaries, while incorporating
sufficient flexibility to evolve with digital economies (Group of central banks (2021b)).
Finally, there are broader considerations for central banks arising from user “take-up” of CBDC
(ie the use of CBDC as a means of payment and potentially a store-of-value). The speed of user take-up
and the potential need for transition arrangements as well as other potential safeguards are beyond the
scope of this report but are necessary issues for central banks to consider in designing a potential CBDC
that enhances monetary and financial stability
This report has focused primarily on potential risks to financial stability that could arise from the
introduction of a CBDC and how to mitigate these risks. These risks need to be considered alongside
the benefits and counterfactuals. A CBDC has the potential to offer new opportunities for innovation,
which may benefit banks, and non-bank/third-party providers of financial services, supporting a
competitive and diverse financial system. This could facilitate new opportunities for innovation and
increase the resilience of the system overall – subject to authorities ensuring appropriate regulation
of all parties. At the same time there is also continuing change in payment methods and emergence
of new forms of privately issued digital money, some of which pose risks themselves.
The introduction of a CBDC could prompt some changes that affect the functioning of the
financial system in ways similar to the introduction of new forms of private money such as stablecoins.
The extent and nature of these changes would depend on take-up, which remains highly uncertain
and depends on design features and attractiveness relative to deposits. The choice of a remuneration
approach, and competitiveness with bank deposits, would likely be a key factor determining take-up,
but non-pecuniary factors ranging from privacy to payments access could be important as well.
Potential benchmarks for take-up would include factors that are specific to each jurisdiction, such as
the payment attitudes and volume of currency in circulation.
A material shift from bank deposits to CBDC – which would be possible for example if the
holdings of CBDCs by individual users were left unconstrained – could have a non-trivial, long-term
impact on bank lending and intermediation, although these impacts may be limited for many
plausible levels of CBDC take-up and if the system has time to adjust. Estimates from a simple, partial
model suggest that a large shift from bank deposits to CBDC could plausibly lead to a fall in bank
profitability in benign circumstances, assuming normalized monetary conditions. This could in turn
affect lending conditions and/or the resilience of banks. It could imply more reliance by banks on
wholesale market funding. Greater take-up levels would have a greater impact on the financial
system. Moreover, the impact could be exacerbated if the response of the banking system strains the
capacity of funding markets. This is more likely to occur if deposits were lost over a shorter time
frame. The implications could also be larger for some types of bank business model than others.
In the context of negative interest rates, decisions around whether and how to remunerate
a CBDC become more complex, given the presence of unremunerated cash, and potential
18 Central bank digital currencies: financial stability implications
competition with bank deposits or money instruments with negative interest rates. Given the
prevalence of negative interest rates and current proximity to the zero-lower bound in many
jurisdictions, issues related to negative interest rates require further consideration.
Yet additionally, the existence of unconstrained CBDCs, or other digital money, as an easily
accessible, safe asset could increase the risk of systemic banks runs and make money market funds
or instruments more susceptible to abrupt outflows. A similar effect could arise for other sectors seen
as relatively safe, notably in money markets.
That said, the presence of a CBDC could, over time, increase diversity of providers of
payments and other financial intermediation services. The introduction of a CBDC could make it easier
for new financial service providers to enter the market for payments services or to improve the
competition amongst banks and non-banks for lending – increasing the diversity of financial service
provision. This in turn, subject to appropriate regulation of all participants, could increase the
resilience of financial service provision to shocks and reduce the impact of financial crises overall.
Central banks can introduce safeguards in a CBDC framework to reduce financial stability
risks, notably by limiting take-up permanently or on a transitional basis. Financial stability risks also
need to be carefully considered for private digital money and are potentially more challenging to
manage than for CBDC. Depending on the specific rationale in a jurisdiction for pursuing CBDC,
combinations of limits on CBDC holdings or transactions, or remuneration disincentives, could be
deployed to moderate take-up. Calibration of limits or remuneration frameworks would need to
balance moderating the take-up of CBDC, specifically substitution with private money and deposits,
with allowing a CBDC to fulfil its public policy objectives. Technical solutions that allow for monitoring
and implementation of limits would also need to be considered in the design phases of a CBDC, and
some safeguards may be easier to implement than others.
A CBDC (or certain new forms of privately issued digital money) could also change run
dynamics in a stress, and the latent level of liquidity risk banks face. Authorities might need to
consider adjusting prudential liquidity requirements or other measures such as the terms of their
crisis lending facilities. The potential for more abrupt flows out of money market instruments may
also demand further consideration of prudential regulation in that sector. And to the extent that
CBDCs encourage new entrants and the growth of non-bank financial services, authorities would
need to ensure appropriate regulation of these entities.
Overall, considerable further work is needed to fully understand the full range of effects and
quantify the implications for financial stability from CBDCs (including the risks and also the
opportunities to enhance financial stability as the payments landscape continues to evolve), and the
various design, remuneration and safeguard options. The novelty of a CBDC creates many difficult to
answer questions around firstly, the extent of potential take-up, and secondly how banks, nonbanks
and other providers might react to its introduction. Initial, illustrative analysis has helped shed some
light on partial responses to changes in bank funding, but they have also revealed that more
consideration is needed of when behavioural responses could lead to bigger impacts, and when
offsetting affects might appear. Furthermore, much attention to date has been focused on risks to
banks, and more consideration of the impact on money markets may be worthwhile. Observations
from early CBDC launches and pilot schemes could be useful in providing more information.
Comments
Post a Comment