the yale men
n June 1, 2001, 2,920 people showed up for dinner at the Jacob
Javits Convention Center on the western edge of Manhattan.
They had come to participate in what had become one of the
great rites of the summer: the annual gala of the Robin Hood Foundation, the charity conceived by Paul Tudor Jones in the wake of the crash
of 1987. After thirteen years in operation, Robin Hood had distributed
over $90 million to organizations that fought poverty, teen pregnancy,
and illiteracy in New York City, and the gathering in 2001 promised to
take the crusade to the next level. The guests filed into a cocktail area that
mixed the vibe of a disco with a sort of rain-forest aesthetic: Hundreds of
green poles rose nearly twenty feet into the air; an image of green treetops
was projected onto the wall; a constantly shifting green light scanned the
room for celebrities. There was the actress Meg Ryan, the baseball personality Keith Hernandez, and the newsman Tom Brokaw—and there were
many, many hedge-fund managers. The caterers went about their business
with paramilitary intensity. Traffic cops armed with fl uorescent batons
directed servers around the kitchen.1
The Robin Hood dinner was proof that Soros’s epitaph for hedge
funds had been delivered prematurely. Stan Druckenmiller himself was a
sponsor of the event, having returned to the markets almost immediately
266 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
after leaving Quantum—he was now running his own fi rm, Duquesne
Capital Management. A who’s who of the titans turned out at the gala,
paying $5,000 per ticket and bidding lustily in the auction. One guest
forked over $540,000 for the privilege of lunch with a leading financial
mogul. Another shelled out $260,000 for the “Be a Star” package, which
included a part as an extra in Russell Crowe’s A Beautiful Mind, a walk-on
in Drew Barrymore’s The Duplex, and dinner with the Hollywood power
couple Catherine Zeta-Jones and Michael Douglas. Paul Tudor Jones’s
wife, Sonia, bid $420,000 to attend a yoga lesson taught by Madonna and
Gwyneth Paltrow—“Come on, people, you can’t stretch by yourselves!”
the comedian Jerry Seinfeld urged as he auctioned off this item. Once the
selling was over, a slice of the wall around the dining room dropped away.
Cannons spewed confetti on the guests. Robert Plant, known to not-soyoung members of the audience as Led Zeppelin’s lead singer, strutted
onto the dance fl oor.
By the end of that evening in 2001, Jones’s foundation had pulled in
$13.5 million, demonstrating that hedge-fund wealth had become a social
force of some significance. Meanwhile, George Soros’s Open Society Institute, the oldest and largest of the hedge-fund philanthropies, was disbursing $450 million per year; and in 2002 Arki Busson, who fed capital to
Paul Jones and others from investors in Europe, created ARK—Absolute
Return for Kids—which became the Robin Hood equivalent in London.
And yet the greatest philanthropic impact of hedge funds lay elsewhere—
not so much in the charities that they bankrolled as in the profi ts that
accrued to the endowments that invested with them. By the early 2000s,
billions of dollars of hedge-fund earnings had flowed into the coffers of
universities, boosting their ability to finance everything from scientifi c
research to scholarships for students from poor families. And just as this
bonanza changed the outlook for learning, so it changed the character of
hedge funds too. As they took in institutional money, hedge funds grew
larger, slicker, and more methodical in style. They were emerging as a real
industry.
The pioneer of this alliance between endowments and hedge funds
was David Swensen of Yale University. He was tall, angular, ascetic, and
T H E YA L E M E N 267
cerebral—a “stiff-backed midwesterner,” one friend called him—and he
was possessed above all by a fierce sense of moral purpose. Growing up
in River Falls, Wisconsin, he founded a recycling club through a church
group; his mother and sister were Lutheran ministers; and his ambition
was to follow in the state’s progressive political tradition and be elected to
the Senate. But after enrolling in Yale’s economics PhD program, Swensen
took a different turn. He befriended the future Nobel laureate James
Tobin. He got to know Wall Street’s preeminent bond fi rm, Salomon
Brothers, which provided market data for his dissertation. He developed a
passion for finance and for the Yale environment.
When Swensen completed his doctorate in 1980, Salomon immediately
hired him, and he thrived on the competitive culture of Wall Street. He
helped to make financial history the following year by playing a role in the
creation of the first currency swap, a deal between IBM and the World Bank
that allowed the technology company to hedge its exposure to Swiss francs
and German marks; and in 1982 he was lured away by Lehman Brothers to run the bank’s fledgling swaps desk.2
But in 1985, when his former
professors lobbied him to take over Yale’s troubled endowment, Swensen
accepted happily. He gave up investment-banking bonuses for a book-lined
office on the university campus, taking a pay cut of 80 percent. Years later,
a Wall Street admirer remarked that Swensen could have been a billionaire
if he had applied his talents to running a hedge fund. “What’s the matter
with you?” the admirer asked. “A genetic defect,” Swensen responded.3
When Swensen took over the endowment at Yale, more than four fi fths
of its assets were invested in U.S. stocks, bonds, and cash, with only a tenth
in so-called alternative investments—in short, it resembled most other college endowments. For a young man returning from the innovative world
of Wall Street, this seemed a little tame; besides, it was an affront to the
research of Swensen’s mentor, James Tobin, who had helped to advance
the idea that portfolio diversification is the one free lunch in economics.
In a modern financial system, Swensen reasoned, diversifi cation should
mean more than simply holding a broad mix of U.S. bonds and equities:
Assets such as foreign equities, real estate, private equity, oil, gas, and
timber all offered ways to add equity-type returns while diversifying risk
268 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
substantially. Then there was another kind of asset that took Swensen’s
fancy. He called it “absolute return,” and over the next years the term
entered the investment lexicon. It was a synonym for hedge funds.
The moralist in Swensen had no desire to help hedge-fund managers
earn fortunes. But the economist in Swensen was impressed by the design
of hedge-fund incentives. He knew that the larger an investment fund, the
harder it was for a fund manager to generate returns, so he disliked fees
that were tied to the volume of capital a manager amassed, preferring the
performance fees that accounted for most hedge-fund revenues. He recognized that performance fees alone can encourage too much risk—hedgefund managers get a fifth of the upside but pay no equivalent penalty if
they blow up—so he sought out hedge-fund managers who had their own
savings in their funds and was encouraged to discover many of them. But
what really interested Swensen was the scale and source of hedge-fund
profits. Hedge funds promised equity-sized returns that were uncorrelated
with the market index, offering the free lunch of diversifi cation.
It took a little while for Swensen to recognize the potential in hedge
funds. In 1987, two years after he assumed the helm at the endowment,
he received a visit from a Yale alumnus who had heard of his appointment
at a homecoming football game. The visitor said he had a small fund out
on the West Coast; perhaps Yale might want to invest with him? Swensen
and his deputy, Dean Takahashi, listened to the pitch.
“We’re not interested,” they told the supplicant. “We’ll never be
interested.”
THE SUPPLICA NT WAS TOM STEYER, A ND HIS HEDGE
fund was called Farallon. Steyer sported a sweeping red-blond parting,
jaunty sideburns, and faded woven wristbands; though he had grown up
in New York, he exuded the vibe of his adopted home of San Francisco.
He was ebullient, funny, and comfortable in his own skin; he could fill
a conversation with mental and athletic juice, running with ideas like
the soccer star that he had been in college. Steyer came equipped with
another quality that would appeal to Swensen later on: He had an acute
T H E YA L E M E N 269
sense of right and wrong, which colored everything from his lifestyle to
his approach to business. Long after Steyer built Farallon into one of the
world’s biggest hedge funds, he was renowned for his beat-up car, his habit
of flying commercial, and his utter indifference to fashion.4
His offi ce
consisted of a desk in the middle of an open-plan hallway. Behind him
was a breathtaking panorama of San Francisco, except that Steyer kept
the blinds down.5
Steyer founded Farallon in 1985, the same year that Swensen took over
the Yale endowment. He was motivated partly by a desire to escape Wall
Street for a life on the West Coast and partly by that sense of justice. As
a young analyst at Morgan Stanley, he had been upset to discover that
investment-bank advisers can be paid for being wrong; sounding convincing mattered more than actually being right, since the objective was
simply to extract fees from the clients. After a stint at Stanford’s business
school, Steyer had worked at Goldman Sachs for the merger- arbitrage unit
run by Robert Rubin, the future Treasury secretary. This suited him better: Goldman got paid in this business only when Goldman was right,
though the distribution of the profits among employees sometimes generated arguments. The way Steyer saw things, setting up an independent fund was the logical next step. He had begun at a fi rm that took no
responsibility for bad investment calls. He had moved to a firm that took
responsibility collectively but that did not always recognize an individual’s
contribution. Now, by starting a freestanding fund, Steyer would be out
there on his own, with no buffer between the quality of his investment
calls and the rewards he got from them.
Steyer rented some cheap space in downtown San Francisco with a
couple of desks, one for himself and one for a partner.6
He would ride
the elevator up to his office at 5:30 in the morning, clutching his coffee
and doughnut, ready to analyze the merger action at the start of the New
York trading day. The investment style he practiced was the same one he
had learned at Goldman Sachs. When a takeover bid was announced, the
stock in the target company would move most of the way to the bid price:
For example, if it had been trading at $30 and the bid was for $40, it
might shoot up to $38. This presented Steyer with a choice. If he bought
270 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
the stock and the merger was consummated, he would pocket another
$2 per share; but if the merger was called off and the stock fell back to
its old price, he would forfeit $8. Knowing whether to risk $8 to make
$2 required a special skill. You had to judge whether antitrust regulators
would block the merger, or whether shareholders would revolt. You had
to estimate the odds that another suitor might emerge stage left, perhaps
pushing the stock above $40.
Steyer pursued his work with a competitive passion that sometimes
seemed overboard. When he took some losses in the crash of 1987, he
started to show up at three in the morning, accompanied by his wife, who
feared for his stability.7
But despite the hit in 1987, Steyer did extremely
well: An arbitrageur who analyzes mergers from a desk at Goldman Sachs
can analyze them pretty much as well from a desk in San Francisco, especially when his body and soul are tied up in his performance. By buying
target companies in deals that would be consummated, Steyer eked out
profits, month by month. And by shorting the acquiring firms, he hedged
out the risk from general market movements.
Toward the end of the 1980s, Steyer expanded his horizons. This was
partly a survival strategy, since the takeover boom skidded to a halt when
the junk-bond market collapsed in 1989, leaving merger arbitrageurs with
few mergers to analyze. But Steyer was playing offense too: The junk-bond
collapse created an opportunity to apply his analytical skills in a different context.8
The companies at the center of the junk-bond market fi led
for bankruptcy one by one; and an investor who could figure out which
piece of busted debt to buy was likely to profit handsomely. To make
matters even better, pension funds, mutual funds, and other institutional
investors were forced sellers of junk: Their rules forbade them to hold the
bonds of companies in default, so they were compelled to concede bargains to nimble players such as Farallon.9
When Drexel Burnham Lambert, the kingpin of the junk-bond market, fi led for bankruptcy in 1990,
Steyer bought a large slice of its debt at cents on the dollar; and when he
sold his stake in 1993, Farallon’s portfolio chalked up a 35 percent profi t.10
With the Drexel transaction Steyer had scored a dazzling double. He had
T H E YA L E M E N 271
profited from the mergers made possible by Drexel’s bonds, and he had
profi ted again from Drexel’s implosion.
Steyer had created what would later be known as an “event-driven”
hedge fund. He specialized in events that caused existing prices to be
wrong—moments when a disruption suddenly rendered the market’s settled view inoperative. The moment before a takeover bid, a company’s
share price embodies the verdict of investors who have projected future
earnings: The price is efficient in the sense that it has been analyzed to
death already. The moment after the takeover bid, the old calculations
are scrambled: Now the analysts have to look at the size of the takeover
premium, the time until it is likely to be realized, the rate at which it
should be discounted, and so on. In similar fashion, an event such as a
bankruptcy scrambles yesterday’s consensus on the value of a company’s
bonds. Again, the challenge is to look afresh at the cash flows that each
busted bond seems likely to generate.
Even before the Drexel coup, the news of Steyer’s performance had
reached the ears of David Swensen. Steyer was making excellent money
irrespective of whether the stock market was up or down—he offered
diversification. Steyer was generating profits by focusing on occasions
in which settled prices were scrambled; to a financial economist attuned
to the limits of the efficient-market hypothesis, the success did not look
merely lucky.11 These two factors were enough to make Swensen reconsider his initial refusal to invest in Farallon. But before he went further,
Swensen had to take the measure of Steyer the man. He wanted partners
with integrity, and he wanted something more as well. Beating the market
was only possible for people with a sort of obsessive passion. “Great investors tend to have a ‘screw loose,’ pursuing the game not for profit, but for
sport,” Swensen wrote later.12
As Yale did its due diligence, it found that Steyer had all the qualities
that the endowment could hope for. This guy was not running a hedge
fund because he craved luxury: You just had to look at his office to see
that. This guy shared Swensen’s passion for pure compensation incentives:
He insisted that Farallon employees keep their liquid savings in the fund
272 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
so that they would feel the pain if they lost money.13 Steyer also embraced
the convention of a “high-water mark,” meaning that if his fund was
down he would take no further fees until he earned the money back for
his investors.14
In the fall of 1989, Swensen flew to San Francisco. He visited Farallon’s
scruffy office and approved of what he saw; but over a cheap lunch with
Steyer and another Farallon partner, Fleur Fairman, Swensen repeated his
earlier verdict that Yale would not invest with them. Hedge funds, he said
bluntly, would stiff their clients if their strategies went wrong. Rather than
working without compensation to earn the capital back, as the “highwater mark” promise suggested, hedge funds would simply close up shop,
reopening under a new name with a fresh set of investors.
“Look, the reason we don’t want to do this honestly is in this format,
if you lose money, you won’t want to earn it back. You’ll close down and
start a new fund. That’s the problem with the whole format.”
Steyer might have argued back, but Fairman beat him to it. “That’s
a bunch of bullshit!” she exclaimed, and Swensen could see that she was
furious. “If you think that’s who we are then we don’t want your money
anyway!” Fairman carried on. “You have no idea who we are! It’s just
ridiculous that you’d say that!”15
This was a better response than Swensen could possibly have wished
for. He had found the integrity he sought: Fairman took her decency so
seriously that she flew off the handle when you questioned it.
In January 1990, Yale invested with Farallon. The university injected
$300 million into Steyer’s fund, boosting his capital to a total of $900 million and kick-starting a gradual change in the social impact of hedge funds.
SWENSEN’S PARTNERSHIP WITH STEYER BEGAN THE REpositioning of Yale, ultimately affecting the investment style of nearly
all endowments. Until the Farallon deal, Yale had a smattering of holdings in private equity and “real assets” such as real estate, but nothing in
hedge funds. Half a decade later, in 1995, the allocation to hedge funds
had jumped to 21 percent, with another 31 percent in private equity and
T H E YA L E M E N 273
real assets.16 Other universities followed, with a lag: For a typical university endowment, the allocation to hedge funds rose from nothing in
1990 to 7 percent in 2000.17 In the years after the dot-com crash, endowments that experimented with hedge funds were rewarded particularly
well: From July 2000 through June 2003, the S&P 500 lost 33 percent of
its value while the HFR index of hedge funds gained 10 percent. Yale itself
was up 20 percent over this period, and a couple of years later, when the
university celebrated the twentieth anniversary of Swensen’s arrival, his
investment decisions were celebrated for generating $7.8 billion of the $14
billion in the Yale endowment—that was the amount by which he had
outperformed the average university fund during his tenure. Fully $7.8
billion: It was a staggering number! With Swensen eclipsing storied education philanthropists such as Harkness and Mellon, hedge funds became
more than just vehicles for the rich to get richer. By 2009 roughly half the
capital in hedge funds came not from individuals but from institutions.
The rush of endowment money into hedge funds ensured that there
was no need at all to write an epitaph for the industry. At the start of
2000, when Soros proclaimed that the hedge-fund era was over, hedgefund assets had stood at $490 billion. By the end of 2005, they stood at
$1.1 trillion. Soros’s epitaph was at least partially apt for his own type of
trader: The first years of the new century were a relatively lean time for
macro hedge funds. But event-driven funds such as Farallon made up for
that.18 Farallon’s assets ballooned from $8 billion in 2002 to $16 billion
in 2006, and imitators crowded in. Och-Ziff, created by another veteran
of the Robert Rubin arbitrage group at Goldman Sachs, grew from $6 billion to $14 billion over the same period. Perry Capital, another Rubin
offshoot, grew from $4 billion to $11 billion. This “Rubin three” soon
exceeded the Commodities Corporation three in terms of asset size. By
2006, Caxton, Tudor, and Moore marshaled a combined total of $35 billion, $6 billion less than the total for Farallon, Perry, and Och-Ziff; and
a host of other products of the Rubin arbitrage group, including Frank
Brosens of Taconic Capital, Eric Mindich of Eton Park, and Edward
Lampert of ESL Investments, were flourishing. In the hedge-fund family
tree, perhaps only Julian Robertson had more offspring.
274 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
It was not just that returns earned by event-driven funds were impressive. From the point of view of endowment managers, who reported to
oversight committees that asked skeptical questions, the returns were
pleasingly explicable. Macro traders like Paul Tudor Jones might talk
about Kondratiev waves and breakout points: To the average investment
committee, this was hocus-pocus. But event-driven funds like Farallon
involved no mystery at all. These guys studied legal labyrinths. They
understood the odds that a given merger would go through. They could
judge how a particular slice of subordinated debt was likely to be treated
by a particular bankruptcy judge in a particular court. With this sort of
edge, of course they would make money! Besides, the endowment oversight committees could grasp that event-driven funds succeeded because
others were hobbled. Institutional investors had rules that forced them
to sell the bonds of companies in default, so they were required to cede
profits to Steyer and his imitators. The more endowments displaced rich
individuals as the chief investors in hedge funds, the more it mattered
that hedge-fund strategies could be understood. A rich investor can bet
his personal fortune on a mysterious genius if he so chooses. Endowment
committees must protect their backs with PowerPoint presentations.
Along with profits and transparency, the event-driven merchants
promised consistency. They used very little leverage, which in the wake
of Long-Term’s blowup was a selling point in itself; partly as a result,
their returns were almost miraculously steady.19 Farallon’s consistency
was legendary: Between 1990 and 1997, there was not a single month in
which the fund lost money. As a result, Farallon’s Sharpe ratio, a measure
of returns adjusted for risk, was roughly three times higher than that of
the broad stock market, making it an overwhelmingly attractive place for
endowments to park savings.20 Even during the height of the dot-com
madness, Steyer sailed along serenely. He did not ride the bubble like
Stan Druckenmiller. He did not get run over by it like Julian Robertson.
Instead, he applied his methods to analyzing the epic takeover battles of
the era, hedging out the market risk as he did so. Naturally, this strategy looked good when the market collapse sank both Druckenmiller and
Robertson.
T H E YA L E M E N 275
In sum, the event-driven hedge funds were producing understandable,
unvolatile returns—returns, moreover, that reflected pure investment skill
and were uncorrelated with the market index. This was the holy grail, the
elixir that endowment consultants called alpha, and institutional capital
flooded into their coffers. And yet the triumph of the event-driven hedge
funds was not bereft of risk. Even the stars like Farallon had vulnerabilities that few suspected.
BY THE LATE 1990S, FAR A LLON WAS OPER ATING OUT OF
a fashionable skyscraper in yuppie downtown San Francisco. The commander’s work space was modest as always, but there was a Henry Moore
sculpture outside and a lawn where beautiful people ate organic sandwiches. From this bastion of serenity, Steyer’s small operation was venturing to ever farther-flung frontiers. In 1998 it launched a merger-arb
operation in London, arriving within a few months of its rivals, Och-Ziff
and Perry Capital. It bought a stake in Alpargatas, a bankrupt Argentine textile and shoe maker. It installed new managers at Alpargatas and
restructured the firm’s debt; soon some two thousand idled workers found
themselves employed again, and Farallon had proved that it could do well
by doing good in a frontier economy.21 But nothing could match what was
about to follow. In November 2001, Farallon set out to buy the biggest
bank in Indonesia.
Farallon’s target, Bank Central Asia, had been founded by Liem
Sioe Liong, who had been Indonesia’s richest man and a firm friend of
the country’s modernizing dictator, Suharto. Liem’s empire was said to
account for 5 percent of Indonesia’s output, and the secret of his success
was best illustrated by the flour business. Playing on his connections to
Suharto, Liem arranged for Indonesia’s government to sell him imported
wheat at a subsidized price and then to buy it back from his fl our mills
at a markup—nice work if you can get it.22 Untroubled by competitive
pressure, Liem’s flour mill in Jakarta grew to be the largest in the world;
the second-largest, in Surabaya, belonged to Liem also. And although
the mills were supposed to sell their flour back to the government, an
276 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
impressive quantity found its way to another Liem enterprise, Indofood,
which consequently controlled 90 percent of Indonesia’s instant-noodles
market. In similar fashion, Liem prospered mightily in coffee, sugar, rubber, cement, rice, and cloves. Naturally, a man of his standing needed his
own bank. Naturally, the bank was the nation’s largest.
By the time Farallon came on the scene, Liem’s empire had imploded.
The patriarch had hedged his political risk by awarding Suharto relatives large stakes in his firms.23 But the currency crisis that cost Soros and
Druckenmiller a fortune triggered a slow-motion revolution in Indonesia,
culminating in the fall of the Suharto government. From that moment on,
Liem’s political insurance policy became a target painted on his chest—
friends of the fallen president were now enemies of the people. Rioters
broke into Liem’s compound, set his cars ablaze, and smashed his Chinese
vases. Shorn of their political protection, Liem’s businesses went bust, and
since many of their loans had come from Bank Central Asia, they threatened to bring the bank down with them. To stem depositors’ understandable panic, the government rescued it.
Farallon was used to event-driven investing, but the collapse of the
Suharto regime was a more extreme event than the average takeover
announcement. Millions of people were driven into poverty; thousands of
demonstrators died in clashes with the police; hundreds of businesses were
looted. Many Indonesians blamed the calamity on Western hedge funds,
and American financiers in the country had been known to receive death
threats. But the more Farallon studied Indonesia, the more the opportunities in the country seemed too good to pass up. Indonesia’s government
was the classic noneconomic seller. The International Monetary Fund was
goading it to off-load the chunks of the private sector that it had been
forced to rescue, and to do so at almost any price; precisely because most
fi nancial players would not set foot in the country, Farallon could expect
limited competition in bidding for distressed assets. During the crises of
1997, hedge funds had profited by betting against governments that set
illogically high prices for their currencies. In the hangover from those
crises, hedge funds would profit by betting against governments that set
illogically low prices for the broken jewels of their economies.
T H E YA L E M E N 277
By the fall of 2001, Farallon had amassed $1 billion worth of holdings
in Indonesia.24 It had bought stakes in PT Semen Cibinong, Indonesia’s
third-largest cement company, and PT Astra International, the largest automaker; it bought the Jakarta Container Port Terminal and sold
it on to Hong Kong–based Hutchison. Then one day Ray Zage, Farallon’s point man in Indonesia, got an unusual message from a government
contact. Bank Central Asia would be reprivatized soon. Perhaps Farallon
would like to bid for it?
It was an astonishing proposal: A small San Francisco fund would take
over the commanding heights of the world’s largest Muslim country. Farallon boasted no more than a few dozen employees; Bank Central Asia had
eight million accounts and eight hundred branches. Farallon was the product of the Goldman arb culture plus a dollop of California cool; Bank Central Asia had been the embodiment of Indonesia’s crony capitalism. Andrew
Spokes, a dapper English banker whom Steyer had recruited from the Goldman Sachs office in Hong Kong, later conceded that the deal was a stretch.
“We were a little off piste,” he conceded, coolly inspecting his cuffs.25 He
sounded like a vintage James Bond who skis an avalanche in a tuxedo.26
By the time the Bank Central Asia opportunity arose, the September
11 terrorist attacks had made Indonesia dicier than ever. A country torn by
economic disaster and political revolution seemed vulnerable to Islamist
extremism. The huge California state retirement fund, CalPERS, was
getting ready to announce that it would not invest in Indonesia, period;
even the intrepid Goldman Sachs tightened the limits on the Indonesian
exposure that it would tolerate.27 The Farallon team began to behave differently on its periodic visits to the country, especially when it found itself
in concentrated clumps of foreigners. Ray Zage viewed the area between
the customs checkpoint and the taxi rank at the airport as a natural kill
zone. “I remember Ray observing it would be great not to be mowed down
there,” Spokes recalled matter-of-factly.28
Farallon proceeded to weigh up the case for buying Bank Central Asia.
The discipline of event-driven investors is to zone out the chatter and the
panic and focus on value—when market prices cease to be a guide, you
decide what to pay for an asset based on the cash flows it will generate.
278 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
Spokes pushed past Bank Central Asia’s reputation as the center of Liem’s
crony-capitalist empire and focused on three facts. Since nationalization,
the bank’s rotten loans to Liem’s enterprises had been replaced with special recapitalization bonds, so that instead of depending on repayments
from busted crony companies, BCA depended on repayments from the
Indonesian state: BCA was really less a bank than a government bond
fund. Moreover, BCA enjoyed access to cheap capital from retail depositors: Unlike most other bond funds, BCA came bundled with bargain-
basement leverage.29 Finally, if the local economy picked up, the bank
could start making profitable loans to businesses: BCA was a bond fund,
plus bargain-basement leverage, plus a free option on Indonesia’s recovery.
As to the political risk, Spokes had an answer to that too. Precisely because
the world viewed Indonesia as scary, the post-Suharto leadership could
not afford to treat Farallon capriciously. If they cheated a foreign investor
in a high-profile deal, their reputation would be mud indefi nitely.
After some spirited debate, the Spokes argument for off-piste investing
convinced Steyer and the other partners. Only a year or so earlier, Farallon had had no track record in Indonesia; now it would be bidding for
Bank Central Asia—and going up against a consortium led by Standard
Chartered, a venerable lender with deep roots in the region. In late 2001,
Farallon duly submitted an offer of $531 million, and in March 2002 the
government announced that it had won: A hedge fund from latte land
had bought control of the top bank in the nation. The outcome was so
improbable that conspiracy theories blossomed. Was Farallon a front for
the U.S. government? Was it a Trojan horse for Liem, who dreamed of
reviving his old empire?
Despite the fervid whispers, Farallon’s investment was a blessing for
Indonesia. Farallon installed a new chairman, brought in some consultants, and patiently coaxed the bank out of the Suharto era. By 2006,
when Farallon sold most of its stake to an Indonesian partner, BCA’s share
price had risen 550 percent since the purchase; just as with the Argentine
shoe company, Farallon had shown it could do well by doing good in
a tough country. But Farallon’s investment had another effect too. The
T H E YA L E M E N 279
spectacle of a swashbuckling hedge fund dashing into Indonesia turned
heads in New York and London, and institutional investors began to give
the country a sympathetic second look. In the year leading up to the BCA
purchase, a mere $286 million of net portfolio investment had trickled
into Indonesia; but the following year almost $1 billion of foreign capital
came in, and the year after that brought more than $4 billion.30 Farallon
had scrambled the market’s settled view on all Indonesian assets, setting
the stage for a rebound. An event-driven fund had created an event, helping to turn the economic tide for a nation of 240 million people.31
AS FAR A LLON WAS BIDDING FOR BA NK CENTR A L ASIA,
another adventure half a world away was proceeding less smoothly. Steyer
had gone into business with a Colorado rancher named Gary Boyce, a
flamboyant horse trainer and dreamer of wild dreams about the wealth in
the valley of his childhood. Boyce had approached Farallon with a plan
to buy land in the valley and pump water from the aquifer beneath—the
water could supply Boulder, Colorado Springs, and even Denver. Farallon’s alliance with the Yale endowment made it alert to the potential of
“real assets” like water. Steyer and his team invested.
Southern Colorado’s valleys were as remote in their own way as Jakarta’s
back alleys. To get to Gary Boyce’s homestead, the Farallon people had to
fly to Denver, then drive south for four hours to Alamosa, a small town
with a True Grits Steakhouse, a TropArctic Lube Center, and a store plastered with posters announcing Tecate Imported Beer, Extra Gold Lager,
and new Bud Light Lime—lattes had some competition in this neighborhood. After Alamosa, the visitor pressed on into the San Luis Valley,
past lonely trailer homes, over pancake-flat land covered in harsh scrub,
under cotton-candy clouds that sat motionless on distant mountains. At
the far edge of the valley lay Gary Boyce’s ranch house: a handsome adobe
structure with hollow walls to keep out the heat. Boyce wore shirts with
mother-of-pearl studs on the pockets. On the desk in his study lay a pair
of ornate pistols.
280 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
You could see why Steyer and his team took this man for the perfect
local partner. Boyce grew up poor in the San Luis Valley, then became the
three-time winner of the Colorado dirt-biking championship. He was a
veteran of the politics of water: During a fight over an earlier venture to
tap the San Luis aquifer, he had founded a newspaper called the Needle to
pierce the developer’s bubble.32 And while Boyce was a true local, he was
also worldly: He had grown wealthy training horses for upper-crust Virginians, and wealthier still by marrying an MGM heiress. Confi dent that
Boyce had the moxie to get a new version of the water project launched,
Steyer created a partnership to finance his ambitions. Half the capital came
from Farallon and the other half came from Yale, though Yale played no
role in managing the project.
Backed by Farallon’s money, Boyce duly bought a ranch in the San
Luis Valley in 1994, outbidding the Nature Conservancy, which wanted
to turn the land into a national park. He spent $3 million on an environmental study that showed water could be extracted without damaging
the local soils. He hired lobbyists to plead for the project in the Colorado legislature. Meanwhile, Boyce spent half a million dollars on collecting signatures to get two referenda in front of Colorado’s voters. The
first measure required valley farmers and ranchers to place consumption
meters on their wells; the second forced farmers to pay user fees for some
types of water. Both measures were essential to Boyce’s scheme, since they
would establish a fair price for the resource he would be selling. Boyce
spent another $400,000 on advertisements to build support for his ballot
initiatives, assuring his partners at Yale and in San Francisco that they
would be voted through. Steyer went out to the valley to visit, bringing
his mother along for a vacation. She bonded happily with Boyce and tried
her hand at elk hunting.33
Not everyone was happy, however. The farmers in the valley revolted
against Boyce’s proposals: They were outraged at the prospect of a user fee,
and they claimed that the valley’s sandy soils would clog the meters. As
the arguments grew heated, Steyer began to wonder if he had chosen the
right local partner after all.34 Being born locally was not the same as being
respected locally; perhaps the mother-of-pearl shirt studs and decorative
T H E YA L E M E N 281
pistols marked Boyce out as a poseur, not a regular local with Colorado
credibility. When it came time to vote, in November 1998, Boyce’s water
initiatives were defeated by a large margin. Steyer and his Yale partners
had spent four years and more than $20 million on the project, but now
they had no choice but to recognize its failure.35 Casting about for an
exit, Farallon invited the Nature Conservancy to revive its old plan for a
national park, and the two sides signed a deal at the end of 2001. But then
an obstacle cropped up. Boyce blocked the path to the exit by filing a suit
against Farallon.
Boyce’s argument in court was that the water scheme was still viable.
By bailing out prematurely, Farallon was damaging the value of Boyce’s
stake in the project. The lawsuit delayed the sale to the Nature Conservancy, and soon various onlookers saw an opportunity to make mischief.
Colorado senator Wayne Allard accused Yale of profiting at the expense of
Colorado’s taxpayers, who would bankroll the Nature Conservancy’s purchase, and demanded that Yale lower its asking price of $31.3 million—
even though Yale’s role was merely that of a passive investor.36 Allard
suggested Farallon had misled Yale about the environmental costs of the
project, even though Boyce’s referenda had failed because of the proposed
user fees and meters, not because anyone had shown that his environmental study was faulty. For nearly all of its history, Farallon had tried to
stay out of the headlines, and it was certainly not accustomed to public
abuse from a senator. The involvement with Boyce was growing ever more
uncomfortable.
At the start of 2004, Farallon emerged victorious in its legal struggle
against Boyce, and pressed to conclude the sale to the Nature Conservancy. To buy peace from the critics, Yale announced it would donate
$1.5 million to subsidize the cost to Colorado’s taxpayers. But Farallon
was soon ambushed by another surprise: A bizarre coalition of protesters announced itself on several college campuses. Its leaders declared
that they were part of an “unFarallon campaign” aimed at forcing college endowments to withdraw their capital from Farallon. A protest soccer game at the University of Texas featured players dressed up as crony
capitalists. A “transparency fairy” in a feathered mask waved her wand
282 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
outside Swensen’s office at Yale, willing the endowment to be more open
and accountable.37
The street theater drew attention to a new unFarallon Web site, which
listed all manner of supposedly nefarious activities. It cited Farallon’s
investment in a coal-fired power project in Indonesia: Coal was evil. It
invoked Farallon’s investment in Argentina: The workers had suffered.
It paraded the plight of the tiger salamander on a California golf course
in which Farallon had invested: Unless the golf lords dug some ponds,
the salamanders would be threatened.38 Indeed, Farallon was complicit
in no less a crime than the Iraq war: It owned a $3 million stake in Halliburton, the oil-services firm once headed by Vice President Cheney. The
activists demanded that Farallon’s secretive mastermind meet them to
discuss “the ethics of Farallon’s investment practices.” “We are stakeholders in the investments you make with university money,” they lectured
Steyer, apparently imagining an adversary with a monocle and top hat.
“We do not want our universities to profit from investors that harm other
communities.”39
Steyer did his best to stand up for himself. He wrote to the unFarallon
campaign, pleading that he cared as much as anyone about strong business
values. He wrote to Farallon’s investors, stating the obvious truth that the
Web site was “factually inaccurate.” But the demonstrations continued. In
April students held a rally in front of the office of Yale’s president. They
staged a mock attempt to extract water from an aquifer under the campus,
and they broke ground for a new coal-fired power plant. When the students showed up at a meeting of Yale’s Advisory Committee on Investment
Responsibility, David Swensen’s patience was stretched even further.40
After sitting through a recital of complaints about the endowment’s failure
to disclose the details of its investments, he decided it was time to engage
his tormentors, and he approached them after the meeting: A tall, wiry
figure in a fleece vest, towering over a group of grungy students, arguing
intensely. The students’ demand for more transparency was simply impractical, he explained; in order to compete successfully in markets, investors
must protect proprietary secrets. If Yale wanted to reap the benefits of hedge
funds, it had to promise not to leak information about their dealings: It
T H E YA L E M E N 283
needed to ensure that it was “the highest-quality limited partner possible.”
The students were unmoved. “I think it’s more important to look at Yale as
the highest-quality global citizen,” one of them retorted.41
In picking on Swensen and Steyer, the students had chosen two of
the least appropriate targets in the hedge-fund universe. Far from being a
Cheney acolyte, Steyer was an open-fisted backer of the Democratic presidential candidate, John Kerry. Far from being a money-obsessed monster,
Swensen had missed a chance to be a billionaire because of his “genetic
defect.” But none of this mattered. Hedge funds had grown with the help
of college endowments. They could not expect immunity from the vagaries of college politics.
FARALLON CLOSED THE SALE TO THE NATURE CONSERvancy in September 2004. The water project had been a failure, but the
land had gained value, so Steyer and his partners came out with a small
profit. But the Colorado episode exposed a vulnerability—both in Farallon and in ambitious bargain-hunting funds more generally. Bargains
often lurk in quirky places: in the details of the junk-bond market’s debris,
in postcrisis Indonesia, in tangled feuds between ranchers and farmers in a
remote Colorado valley. To invest successfully in these sorts of situations,
you need to understand the traps in the terrain, and young hedge funds
sometimes lack the manpower to survey it adequately. If Farallon’s people
had spent more time in the San Luis Valley, they might have realized that
Gary Boyce was an unsatisfactory partner.42 But in a fund that doubles its
assets every four or five years, it can be hard to grow in-house expertise as
fast as incoming capital.
But the vulnerability in Farallon-style funds goes deeper than that.
Their returns partly reflect a willingness to buy illiquid investments. If
busted junk bonds represent value, it is probably because most investors are
frightened to buy them—so if you decide you want to sell later, such assets
will be hard to exit. If you buy a bank in Indonesia, the same argument
applies; if you make a mistake, you can’t expect to get out easily. In ordinary liquid markets, prices are fairly efficient and second-guessing them
284 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
is hard. In illiquid markets, by contrast, there are bargains aplenty—but
mistakes can be extremely costly.43
Hedge funds that buy illiquid assets benefit from an accounting quirk
that can flatter their performance. By definition, it is hard to know what
an illiquid asset is worth—you lack the continually updated price discovery that comes with constant trading. As a result, hedge funds with illiquid assets don’t so much report their profi ts as estimate them—there is no
objective price for much of what they hold, so they have to come up with
a subjective value. In a few cases, hedge funds may take advantage of this
murkiness to exaggerate their returns, though this game is not sustainable. But even if funds make every effort to report their results honestly,
they cannot help but “smooth” them. A hedge fund may estimate the
value of an illiquid asset every few weeks; if it rises 5 percent and then
falls back within that period, it will be recorded simply as fl at—with the
result that some sharp volatility along the way is not acknowledged. As a
result, hedge funds with illiquid assets are not as stable as their numbers
suggest. Their risk-adjusted returns look wonderful because some of the
risk goes unreported.
But the biggest danger for buyers of illiquid assets is that, in a crisis,
these assets will collapse the hardest. In moments of panic, investors crave
securities that can be easily sold, and the rest are shunned ruthlessly. LongTerm Capital’s apparently diverse portfolio concealed a single bet that the
world would be stable: When this proved wrong, apparently unrelated
positions collapsed simultaneously because many of them boiled down
to an attempt to harvest a premium for holding illiquid assets. Likewise,
apparently diversified event-driven funds may be taking a concentrated
bet on illiquid investments. In 1998, Long-Term Capital paid the ultimate
price for taking too much of this sort of risk. In 2008, buyers of illiquid
assets paid heavily again, as we shall see presently.
13
The Code Breakers
Not so many hedge funders have been to East Setauket. It is an
hour’s drive from Manhattan, along the Long Island Expressway; it is separated from the hedge-fund cluster in Greenwich
by a wedge of the Atlantic Ocean. But this sleepy Long Island township is
home to what is perhaps the most successful hedge fund ever: Renaissance
Technologies. Starting around the time that David Swensen invested in
Farallon, Renaissance positively coined money; between the end of 1989
and 2006, its flagship fund, Medallion, returned 39 percent per year on
average.1
By the mid-2000s, Renaissance’s founder, James Simons, had
emerged as the highest hedge-fund earner of them all. He was not the
world’s most famous billionaire, but he was probably its cleverest.
Simons was a mathematician and code breaker, a lifelong speculator and
entrepreneur, and his extraordinary success derived from the combination
of these passions. As a speculator, he had dabbled in commodities since his
student days, acquiring the trading bug that set him up for future stardom.
As an entrepreneur, he had launched a string of businesses; the name of
his company, Renaissance Technologies, reflected its origins in high-tech
venture capital. As a code cracker, Simons had worked at the Pentagon’s
secretive Institute for Defense Analyses, where he learned how to build a
research organization that was closed toward outsiders but collaborative on
286 MORE MONEY THAN GOD
the inside. As a mathematician, he had affixed his name to a breakthrough
known as the Chern-Simons theory and won the American Mathematical Society’s Oswald Veblen Prize, the highest honor in geometry. In an
expression of his diverse passions, Simons used a wedding gift to speculate
successfully on soybeans, got fired from the Institute for Defense Analyses
for opposing the Vietnam War, and drove from Boston to Bogotá on a
Lambretta motor scooter—all while still in his twenties. Having grown to
know Colombia at the end of that road trip, he teamed up with some local
friends to launch a tile factory in the country.
Simons’s early adventures in markets had little to do with mathematics.
He traded commodity futures on the basis of hunches about demand and
supply, riding the wild booms and busts of the 1970s. But the mathematician inside him yearned to substitute models for seat-of-the-pants judgment, and he loved the idea of a machine that would do his trading for
him. Starting in the late 1970s, Simons recruited a string of outstanding
mathematical minds to help create such a machine. There was Leonard
Baum, a cryptographer who had worked with Simons at the Institute for
Defense Analyses. There was James Ax, a winner of the American Mathematical Society’s foremost prize in number theory. And there was Elwyn
Berlekamp, a Berkeley mathematician who was yet another veteran of the
Institute for Defense Analyses. The names and ownership structures of
Simons’s various ventures changed along with the collaborators he drew
into his net. He had an investment fund in Bermuda and a company on
the West Coast, as well as the operation on Long Island, where he had
chaired the math department of Stony Brook University before quitting
in 1977 to focus on his businesses.
It was not just that Simons’s recruits were intellectually formidable.
Their experiences in cryptography and other aspects of military communications were relevant to finance. For example, Berlekamp had worked on
systems that send signals resembling “ghosts”—faint traces of code in seas
of statistical noise, not unlike the faint patterns that hide in broadly random and effi cient markets. Soldiers on a battlefi eld need to send messages
to air cover that are so wispy and translucent that they won’t betray their
positions: Not only must the enemy not decode the messages; it must not
THE CODE BREAKERS 287
even suspect that someone is transmitting. To Berlekamp, the battlefi eld
adversaries fooled by such systems bore a striking resemblance to economists who declared markets’ movements to be random. They had stared
at the ghosts. They had seen and suspected nothing.2
The Simons team
took their experience with code-breaking algorithms and used it to look
for ghostly patterns in market data. Economists could not compete in the
same league, because they lacked the specialized math needed to do so.
The early efforts of the Simons team were only moderately successful.
Despite his preeminence as a mathematical modeler, Leonard Baum quickly
tired of the quest for golden algorithms; he read the business papers and
took a huge bet on the British pound, which paid off handsomely. James
Ax stuck with the computer-trading project; but he was a volatile personality and his system’s returns could be volatile also. Still, by 1988 Simons
had built the platform for his later success. Together with Ax he launched
the Medallion Fund, named in honor of the medals the two men had
won for geometry and number theory. Medallion traded commodity and
financial futures on the basis of computer-generated signals; and although
the heart of the system was unremarkable—it was a trend-following model
not unlike the one built at Commodities Corporation more than a decade
before—a small portion of the money was deployed according to a different set of rules. This was the kernel of the future Simons fortune.
Comments
Post a Comment