Coming Battle
In the past decades, privately owned payment systems (e.g., PayPal, M-Pesa, Alipay, and
Square) have gained widespread popularity. Recently, various cryptocurrencies further caused a
fundamental reorientation of domestic and international monetary and payment technologies, as
well as of policies and regulatory frameworks governing payment systems (Brunnermeier, James,
and Landau, 2019; Adrian and Mancini-Griffoli, 2019; Cong, Li, and Wang, 2021a). Many countries
around the globe react to these trends by actively researching on Central Bank Digital Currencies
(CBDCs, see, e.g., Bech and Garratt, 2017; Duffie, 2021; Duffie and Gleeson, 2021), as revealed
by the sharp rise in the number of central banks in the process of developing their own digital
currencies (Boar, Holden, and Wadsworth, 2020; Boar and Wehrli, 2021).1 Due to their potential
to be safer, cheaper more efficient, interoperable, and versatile, digital currencies have the potential
to challenge or even replace traditional fiat currency and other online payment systems.
How does the emergence of cryptocurrencies shape international currency competition? Will
digital currencies challenge the dominance of the dollar? Which countries should develop CBDCs
and when? How are various currencies differentially affected? To examine these issues, we develop
a dynamic model of currency competition among multiple countries (or regions with a shared currency or a “systemic hegemonic currency,” as in Carney, 2019) allowing the potential co-existence
of fiat money, cryptocurrencies, and CBDCs, a crypto sector with endogenous growth, and governments’ endogenous efforts for digitizing money. Our theory helps rationalize international trends
in payment and currency digitization, reveals a novel pecking order for CBDC development, and
provides insights concerning the implications of the rise of digital currencies for global competition,
financial innovation, and the future of money.
Specifically, we consider two countries, A and B, each with its fiat currency, and a digital
economy featuring one representative cryptocurrency C as the means of payment. In each period,
one representative OLG household is endowed with perishable consumption goods, which also
serve as the numeraire. Importantly, all three currencies A, B, and C fulfill the standard roles
of money as (i) store of value allowing households to store endowments for desired consumption
timing, (ii) medium of exchange (generating a convenience yield), and (iii) unit of account (not
only domestically but also internationally as a reserve currency). In general, households choose
their holdings of currencies A, B, and C to store their consumption goods over time, trading-off
the currencies’ convenience yield versus inflation and depreciation relative to other currencies which
compromise the store of value function.
Importantly, currencies A and B exhibit an endogenous debasement that decreases with the
strength of countries’ economic fundamentals captured by the countries’ expenses, such as the fiscal
deficit, international trade costs, or the debt service costs countries A and B incur. For example, a
country’s high expenses in terms of the consumption good represent weak economic fundamentals,
cause a high inflation rate and/or depreciation relative to other currencies, and thus imply a weak
national currency. We use A to denote the stronger country and its currency, which is more valuable
in terms of the numeraire and can be viewed as the international reserve currency (e.g., the U.S.
dollar); then B represents a competitor currency, such as the Yuan. To incorporate that foreign
debt is often denominated in the reserve currency, i.e., dollars (Maggiori, Neiman, and Schreger,
2020), or that the U.S. dollar is the global unit of account for invoicing in international trade
(Gopinath, Boz, Casas, D´ıez, Gourinchas, and Plagborg-Møller, 2020), we assume that countries’
expenses are partially denominated in currency A.
Households’ choice between national currencies induces a feedback and can lead to a vicious
circle of inflation and depreciation for weaker currencies. A stronger currency A causes higher
inflation and depreciation of currency B. As currency B depreciates, households substitute more
towards currency A, aggravating inflation and depreciation of currency B. Country A essentially
imposes a pecuniary externality on the relatively weaker country B through a form of dollarization.
The mechanism manifests itself clearly in practice in that the strength of the U.S. dollar and the
trust the world has in U.S. finance (or submission to its technological and military prowess) are
mutually reinforcing.
We then consider the crypto sector in which the growth rates of adoption, usage, and convenience yield of cryptocurrencies endogenously increase with adoption. Cryptocurrencies, including
stablecoins pegged to fiat currencies, constitute a viable substitute for fiat currencies as a store of
3
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4044170
value and medium of exchange. High inflation rates in fiat currencies spur cryptocurrency usage
and growth over time. Intuitively, the absence of strong national fiat currencies implies a vacuum
in the currency space, and private cryptocurrencies emerge to fill the demand. Households also
hold more cryptocurrencies when the underlying technology is more effective or the crypto sector
is more vibrant and creative. Interestingly, the cryptocurrency market acts as a buffer zone amidst
the battle between the two fiat currencies and dampens the degree of dollarization and the vicious
circle of debasement the weaker currency is exposed to.
As the crypto sector grows and the household substitutes toward crytpocurrency, the strong
currency faces more competition from cryptocurrency and depreciates. Because the growth of the
cryptocurrency market depends on the strength of currencies A and B, a stronger currency B could
benefit A by slowing the growth of the crypto-sector which in turn poses less competition to A.
Importantly, the weaker currency B might benefit from the rise of cryptocurrencies, depending on
whether the reduction in competition from A outweighs the increase in competition from cryptocurrencies. The model therefore rationalizes why countries with dominant currencies are more
eager to ban or regulate cryptocurrencies, whereas countries with the weakest currencies, such as El
Salvador and Venezuela, do exactly the opposite and even adopt cryptocurrency as a legal means
of payment.
Our framework also applies to the study of fiat-backed cryptocurrencies, especially stablecoins
which are typically pegged to the U.S. dollar and (partially) backed by U.S. dollar assets (e.g.,
USDC). When a cryptocurrency is backed by reserves consisting of currency A, country A can
capture part of the seigniorage generated from cryptocurrency usage, which strengthens currency
A but weakens other currencies. These findings suggest that the U.S. and the U.S. dollar may benefit
from regulation that requires stablecoin issuers to hold U.S. dollar reserves instead of regulation
that restricts or bans stablecoin issuance. Furthermore, as an alternative to developing CBDCs
to compete with cryptocurrencies, properly regulated stablecoins could potentially allow countries
such as the United States to effectively “delegate” the creation of a digital dollar to the private
sector, whilst sharing the seigniorage revenues.
We next consider the endogenous development of sovereign digital currencies, notably CBDCs.
We model CBDC implementation in a technology-neutral manner that does not rely on any specific
design, simply stipulating that it increases the convenience yield of holding the country’s currency.
Our framework features monetary neutrality and can accommodate possible interest-bearing or
4
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4044170
tax-charging digital currencies. We also recognize that launching CBDCs entails tremendous technological, legal, economic, and operational obstacles, therefore modeling it as a Poisson arrival
process based on the countries’ endogenous (and costly) efforts. Once implemented, CBDCs would
immediately alter the endogenous value of other currencies, whether fiat or digital, as well as other
countries’ incentives to implement their own digital currencies.
Countries’ strategic decisions to implement CBDCs reflect competition from both cryptocurrencies and other fiat currencies. The stronger country’s incentives to launch CBDC mainly derive
from the desire to compete with cryptocurrency. These incentives are high when the cryptocurrency market is in its infancy, because then the launch of CBDC has the largest effect in reducing
competition from cryptocurrencies. This effect gives rise to a “cryptocurrency kill zone” that allows for a preemptive“killer adoption” of the technology. If countries with strong currencies adopt
the technology underlying cryptocurrencies through launching CBDC early enough, they can nip
the future growth and dominance of cryptocurrencies in the bud. Otherwise it is only until the
cryptocurrency market has gained widespread adoption that the implementation of CBDC becomes
unavoidable to avert a takeover by cryptocurrencies. As a result, the stronger country’s strategy
for launching CBDC evolves from an offensive, preemptive tactic to a purely defensive measure.
Regardless, our model predicts that the digitization of money becomes inevitable in the long run.
We find that CBDCs offer the most advantages for countries with non-dominant currencies
(country B), as long as their currencies are not too weak. The non-dominant country B’s incentives
to launch CBDC is stronger than A’s and are primarily shaped by the desire to obtain a technological
first-mover advantage to reduce the degree of dollarization country B is exposed to. Our model
explains why the first CBDCs have been implemented by countries such as China, rather than the
United States. The implementation of CBDCs by such countries poses considerable challenge for
both the cryptocurrency market and stronger fiat currencies, such as the U.S. dollar. We also find
that the dominance of the U.S. dollar causes “entrenchment” that reduces the incentives of the
U.S. to implement CBDC. The recent spike in U.S. inflation, however, potentially undermines the
dominance of the U.S. dollar and improves government incentives to venture into digitizing money.
Depending on the circumstances, decisions to launch CBDC can be either strategic substitutes
or complements. Our model highlights that through the launch of CBDC, weaker currencies may
challenge the dominance of stronger currencies. If it poses a threat on the dominance of the
stronger currency, the implementation of CBDC by weaker countries increases the incentives of
5
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4044170
the stronger country to launch CBDC too, giving rise to strategic complementarity in CBDC
issuance. Consistent with our model, the issuance of CBDC by China is often perceived as such
a threat to the dominance of the U.S. dollar and, accordingly, has led calls to action (Ehrlich,
2020, Forbes) for the U.S. to consider the development of CBDC too. In contrast, CBDC issuance
by stronger countries eliminates the possibility for weaker countries to attain a technological firstmover advantage, thereby always reducing weaker countries’ incentives to develop CBDC and giving
rise to strategic substitutability in CBDC issuance.
We further study the implications of CBDC issuance on the currencies of developing countries
with particularly weak currencies (bigger gap between A and B). Consistent with Brunnermeier
et al. (2019), we find that such countries are particularly prone to digital dollarization: they tend
to suffer the most when a country with strong currency implements CBDC. Yet, these developing
countries and their currencies do not benefit much from implementing CBDC themselves, because
their currency is weak regardless of its underlying technology. Our analysis suggests that developing
countries may benefit from adopting cryptocurrency as a legal means of payment within their own
territory instead of implementing CBDCs as a way to escape from (digital) dollarization. Overall,
the pecking order of CBDC development entails countries with strong but non-dominant currencies
(e.g., China) leading the efforts, followed by countries with the strongest currencies (e.g., the U.S.),
and then by nations with the weakest or non-existent sovereign currencies (e.g., El Salvador).
Finally, we recognize that fiat currencies and traditional bank-payment-rails are inefficient and
fragmented, due to the non-digital nature, the lack of coordination, or the limited competition
in the presence of network effects (Rochet and Tirole, 2003). The development of various digital
currencies therefore can be viewed as financial innovations that eventually benefit households (and
businesses and governments, see, e.g., Duffie, Mathieson, and Pilav, 2021). Our model can be used
to understand how currency competition and the strength of national currencies relate to financial
innovation. In particular, the weakness of national currencies implies a vacuum in the currency
space which favors the emergence of (private) cryptocurrencies and thus financial innovation in the
private sector. Moreover, as crytpocurrencies gain widespread adoption, countries’ incentives to
innovate through the implementation of CBDC increase too, further stimulating financial innovation. Put differently, the dominance of national currencies curbs incentives for innovation both for
governments and the private (financial) sector, which is consistent with the view that competition
stimulates innovation.
4 Conclusions
We develop a dynamic general equilibrium model of global competition among national fiat currencies, cryptocurrencies (stablecoins included), and Central Bank Digital Currencies (CBDCs).
The strength of a country and of its currency are mutually reinforcing, leading to global currency
dominance by the strongest countries. The endogenous rise of cryptocurrencies hurts the stronger
country, but may benefit weaker currencies by reducing fiat competition and dollarization. Reserve requirements on stablecoins mitigate the impact of cryptocurrencies on the fiat currencies
they are pegged to. Because countries’ strategic decisions to implement CBDCs reflect the competition from both emergent cryptocurrencies and other fiat currencies, a pecking order for digital
currency development emerges: Countries with non-dominant currencies tend to have the highestpowered incentives to launch CBDC first so as to attain a technological and cumulative first-mover
advantage; countries with dominant currencies are motivated to launch CBDC early on both to
nip cryptocurrency growth in the bud and to counteract a competitor’s CBDC; nations with the
weakest or without a sovereign currency may opt for cryptocurrencies or stablecoins pegged to a
basket of currencies to avoid (digital) dollarization. In general, weaker national currencies favor the
emergence of cryptocurrencies as competitor and boost countries’ incentives to implement CBDC,
both spurring valuable financial innovations. Our findings help rationalize recent developments in
the digitization of money and provide insights into the future of money and the global battle of
currencies.
Comments
Post a Comment